F UNO A ç Ã O GETULIO VARGAS SEMINÁRIOS DE ALMOÇO DA EPGE Measuring the TFP costs of barriers to trade PEDRO CAVALCANTI FERREIRA (EPGE/FGV) Data: 02/06/2006 (Sexta-feira) Horário: 12h 15 min FGV EPGE Local: Praia de Botafogo, 190 - 11 0 andar Auditório nO 1 Coordenação: Prof. Luis Henrique B. Braido e-mail: [email protected] l\:1easuring the TFP costs of barriers to trade Pedro Cavalcanti Ferreira" Alberto T'rejost EPGE - Funcla(;âo Getulio Vargas INCAE April 28, 2006 Abstract Thís arLicle performs outpnt decompositiolls in ol'del' to meaSUl'e the eJ1ect of trade restrictío11s on total factor procluctívity anel labor productjvity. lt is assumed an ecollomy with two traclable and 1l01l- storable intermediate goods, used in the production of a. nOll-tradable flnal good. The solution of the sLalic Lracle anel fador allocation problem generates implicitly a mapping between factor endOvvmenLS and flnal output, which is then l1sed as an exogenous prodnctíon fUllC- ti011 in the decomposition exerci se. vVe find that for lllidclle income economies vúth high tarilI rates, the effects 01' tracle restrictions are sigllificant; in some cases, enough to a.ttribute to protectionism Olle thil'd of lheir TFP disadvantage, OI' Luore. For lhese cconomics, the impacl o[ trade rcstrictiolls on GDP per worker iH aIso l'ekvant. -------------,--- 'Praia ele Botafogo, 190, Rio de Janeiro,RJ, Brazil, 22253-900. ffTTeinl,((}fr;v.!J'r t Apartado 0GO-4050, Alajuela, Costa Hica. 1 albcTto. tTé)osrfl'incac. cd'u 1 Introduction vVe study and measure the eífects of international tmde paliey on LotaI fae{.or product.ivit.y and output leveIs. As opposed to the prevíous development nceonnting liLcnüure 1 , \ve are not \vorried whether TFP 01' factoni are Inore relevnnt. in explaining output difl'erences. Instead, we perform outpnt de-compositiOl iS frorn a distindive perspcdive. \Ve are interesLed to estirnate in the lirst pInce thc share of TFP difference that is due to distOl'tions cnused by harrÍcrs to 1.rade. 0111' lnodel is adeqnate t.o this task hecause in essence its trade portion is Lhe standard Hecksher-Ohlin moclel. TaríH's distOl't domestíc priccs introducing; an inefficiency in the allocation 01' fadol's between the proctnd ion of inLermediaLe goods, tIms redncíng the value of national proc1lJ(~t at internationaI prices. In addition, the same price dist.ortion causes <tu inefficiclJ(;y in the c110ice of the mix of inLcrrnediatc good hy .t:inal-good procl!lcers. Hence, policy instrulllents that incl'case the cost 01' lnternational trade generate inefficicnt equilibrium allocation of factors aeross industries. In ,tn t,he lllodel, r:his inefficieney lIas an eHect similar to a [aIl in total factor prodlldivily. l'nder a eOllservative calibration of the pal'ameters that determine the a.ggl'ega':.e, statíc importance of trade, we find that barriers to trade be ver)' impxtant for poor countl'ies. Incteed, the model says Lhat for a 1 For C<:tIl COUIl- inSÜtl'Ce, lVIallkiw, Romer anel "Veil (1992) anel Mankiw (1995) present.eei evidellce t.hat factor~: (, f prodnct. iou Others (e.g. HCCOllUt for the bnlk of i UCOllle di ffercnces acrOf:f: conn(.l·ie~:. Klenow anel Hoell'iguez-Clal'e (1991), Prescott (199S) anel Hall and JOlles (1999),) hOWe\Tr, ltave e:stabli:3l!ecl what now seelIB to be a COllsensus that (,ot.al factol' prodllct.iv ity l'; lllOfe relevant. thnn inpllts íu explaíuing; ou t.pllt. differences try WiUl 1/4 of U8 capital/labor ratio, the sLatie elifference bdween having tarifI leveI of 10% OI" 100% can represent. a 10ss of output. of 8.7%. Apply- ing t.he rnodel 1.0 the data of some countries'Nith a protccLionist past - Lhe main excrcise of this art.icle - \ive find that as much as one thirel of their TFP ditfercnce rei ative to the U8 ca,n be attribllted Lo restrÍctive t.rade poliey. Although this is the 1110st elramatic result, we fóund sÍzable productivity anel ontpllt eost.s oI barriers to trade in Iuany cases. vVe use as ou!' main insLrument a model that follows Ferreira anel Trejos (2006). In this framework, it is assumecl an econorny with L\vo tradable anel non-stol'able intermeeliate gooCl<3, used in Lhe product.ion of a nOll-tradnble final good. vVe focus OH the case 01' a small, príce-taking economy. The so- Illtion of the static tmde anel factor aLlocation problem genel'ate:s implicitly a mapping between facto!" enelowments anel final output, \vhich cem then be uHed as ,Ui exogenous productlon fuuction. '[,his (ixmulation is similar to Corden (1971), Trejos (1992) anel Ventura (1997) thaL use a fador-endowrnentH framework to introduce t.rade in a macro model. This artide has fonr sessions in adelition to Lhis introduction. The ncxt session present.s the model used in our development decomposition exercises, whilc sesslon three discusses data anel calibration. 8ession four pre:sents the lnain rcsults and session five concludes. T'ime is disnete and unhonnded. Our representative count.ry i8 small (a price t.aker) anel populat.ed by a continuum of identical, illfinitely-lived individuaIs. There are three goods produced in this economy. Two of those goods, called /1 anel B, are non-stol'able, tradable intermediate produds. They are ouly used to Inal:e the other good, called Y, a final produet that can be consumed 01' invest.ed, but that CéUmot be traded. There are a180 tvvo factors oi" pro- dm:Llon in l.his economy: labor in efficient nnits H and physical capit.al }{. ]'he endow1llcnt oI" labor, mea,sured in efficiency units, 1S given by: \vhere li repI'esents eificiency-units oflahor per \vorker and s stands for schoo1·· ing. The production functio1l8 of A. and B are: Wit.hout lo~s of generality, A i8 labor-illtensive: (ta < 0b. The production 01' the fhml good Y llfles only the intcnnediate goods. Becamc t.hese intennedi- ate gooels are traelab1e, the amounts of t.hem that are used in the production oI" the flnal ,l~ood (denotcd by lmverease a and b) may difIer from the amOllnts produced A anel B. Tbtal ontpnt of Y is given by: (1) '2The l11CHk] follows closely Ji'erreíl"a and Trejo..s (2006) anel hence ít wíll on]y be presenteel !lere a broad ()llt.line of its main components anel the equilíbriulll ~,olution vrhere 8 1S total factor productivity. VVe derive the allocation of capital K anel labor I1 aUlong the productioll 01' A and B, Lhe quantities (J, anel b of intermediale gooels nsed domeslically, and the amount 01' final output Y thaL is produced. Because intennediate goods are assumed t.o be l1on-slorable, and tbe lim-l.l good is nol lradable, lhis i8 a static l)l'Oblel1l, which yields all equilibriul1l l1lapping Y = F(I{, HIT, p) that relates final oulput with factor endmvments. Second, because factors are not tradable, we can simply use that equilibrium mapping F as if it ,;vere an exogenonsly given lechnology. To get Y = F'(K, HIT,p) in equilibrium notice that each period, the equilibrium solntlons for {A, B, 0" b, q. V), T, Ki, Hd must satisfy t,he following properties: 1. Producers 01' intermediate goods choose Ki. Hi In order to maxnmze the period's profit,s: n: A 2. Producers of .flual goods IIlé1Jemuze profits, taking domestic pnces as glven: a, l) -"ll--,' - qa - l) = argmaxíla') a,l; 5 :3. Finnt-' make zero profits, qa -+ b qA B marh:ts dear, anel n;:;ents neither bOITOW from nOI" lencl to the world economy, pA+ E = pa -+ b .'1. Local priccs 01' tradable goods satisfy ali afLer- tnrifI law of one price: q= { Hascel Oll -+ T), if p.(1-+T) if p/ (1 a<A these requisites, one cnn derive Lhe equilibrinm relationship F: 1. lf li' / fi is much lmver [nu1<,:h higher] than t,he world's raL io ({{ / 11) * , onl)' the intermediate ~ood A [El will be produced, as its productioll uses more intensively the relatively abundant labor [capital]. There are criticaI leveis 8} < (J{ / H)* and ,Z2 > (J{ / ITr sueli that if IC/ H S then t he country onl;tj produces A, and if K / H ? only prodnces n. with (apitaI share Z2 81 then the country 'I'hen, Y is a Cobb-Donglas fnnction oI {( and H, LYi! [n/i]' Fllrthermore, the criticaI values s 1 anel z'l, are sen:útive to T. In particular, with higher Lariffs the ecoIlomy is less pronc to specialize, so D"hIDT < O [DzdDT > OL with -s[ as 2. If -+ O [.?:~ -+ cX,.;] T -+ 00. 1-:1 II 1S very dose to (K I 11)* a high cnough tariff wi11 makc the < :rl S thel'e is no Lrade, so a = ./1, b = B. \;Ye have: D:EdDT < O a.nel D:.c'2/DT > ecoIlomy noL trade at aU: There exist O. Also, Xl -+ O anel ::C'l -+ 00 as :E1 T -+ 00, ;I:~, and \vhile where Xl = :E2 if s[ T = O. :3. Ifh,/H is neither too dose llor too far from (lo( /1-1)*, Lhe eCOl1omy wiU proeluce both intermeeliate goods, yet still Ü'aele. In thosc cases holels a result analogous to the Fhdor Price Equél.lization Theorem, \vhich states thaL equilibrium marginal returns of capit.al anel labor are not sen:-;itive to small wtriations in the fador eudowl11.ent. Wlmt that means is Lhat tillal output Y is linear in [( anel H wben K I H E [81, :Ed 01' vvhen K/H E [:E2, Z2]' HeJl(~e, Lhe eqnilibrium relaLionship frolll T-: anel H t.o l' takes Lhe fonn n1 KO"H 1 O~I( F'(K Hlr , - , J))I = '''O!a if K/H < + O:lH if K IH (~ [241('iH1-ci if KIH E SI 181, ;1;11 [Xl,X2] where the values Di. are functions of parametel's, anel are afledeel by p anel T. For a dosed economy it is Lhe case that [:1:1, :X:2) := \Jt+. Con:-;cql1enLly, with- out trade our l1lodel simply collapses to one with the aggregate production 7 funclÍon F"'(1\", HIT,p) values of p anel = Du1 I(ê'H 1 - ct , .a equal to "'ret a + (1 - 1) rl"b. For <-111 F is homogcneous of degl'ee one anel continuous in K and T, H. Ccncricnlly, F 1S also locally concave and continuously eliITerentiable.:1 . F i8 elecrea~;ing in The fac!. that T (strictly elecreasing if k ~ [:1:1, X2]) anel also DF!\ / DT < O. aF[( / ar < Oimplies that a protectionist Lrade policy carries as a conscquence a loss in output, given inputs, anel thereforc a 10ss in measured prodndiviLy. T'he eiTect of r on ouLpuL is not because tariffs appear directly in <tny of 1;l1e proeludion fllnctions, hn(; rather hecanse tarifIs change domestic prices in a way that distorts the decisions of produccrs. The1"e are t\vo reasons \vhy this is so. First, a distorted q inlrodnces an incHiciency in the allocation of J{ anel H betvvcen A anel B, thus reelucing the value of nation.al produd at international prices. Second, the same price distortion causes an illeíIiciency in the choice of a anel b by Y-producers. 'file thüxet.icnl e[Técts of t.aritTs on outpnt are iHusLmted in Figure 1, for the case vvhere 3U T T = () and r =::: ().~i, respectively. .> O )2;lobal concavi1y anel continuous differetltiability is lost becau"e FI( has diserete variatíons (l1p Ol' elown) at the criticaI yalnes 8, and cc,. See Ferreira anel Trejos (200G) for a proof oi" this resulto 1.7S 1.S 1. 2ó 0.75 o.s Q.25 4 Figure 1: Prodndion fundiom; when T=O anel T = 0.3 Note that., gIven K/ H, the open econom~T unambiguously obt.ains more output as F(IC I1IT > O) iH everywhere below F(I.;,', BIT = O). T'his means that in thÍs n1.odel, everything else eqnals, larger barriers to trade imply smaller prodnctivit,y. Moreover, the larger T, Lhe larger Lhe disLance bct,ween F(IC HIT > O) anel F(K, HiT = O), givcn K anel H. Note also Lhat 1,he1"e is all interval [:r] , T2l where the curves coincide. In this sense, the model predids that t,hc costs of protectionism for econornies dose Lo the lcadcrs is either null or very small, vvhich is what one conld expect from a model in wbich trade iR driven by eornparaLive advant,age. We perform level-accolUlting exercises for a variety oi" countrics, to see whaL frnct,ion oI the Lotéil fador prodndiviLy reRidnnI LhaL one mensures usíng a dosed-economy fn.nnevllOrk c<tn ac1,ually he aLtribnLcd to the ineftlciencÍes associated with protectionist trade policy. In this sense ours is a staLic exercise of thc costs of t.rade bnrriers. It is st,atic becanse 'Vve ig110re Lhe impact of i hese balTiers on capital accuIlllllation anel hellce on grO\vth anel income levds in the future. As ".Te have SbO\Vll in our previous paper, t,his 10ng 1'un ourselves efj;{x~t t() of protcctionism policy can be sÍzable. Howcver, \ve 1'esLrict the foll(n;vin~ lnClus/Ui) decomposition cxercise: In (F(k;, hilnTs))/ ln(F(k;, h;IT l )) + ln (F(ki1 husITus))/ln(F(k j , hjITCS)) +- In (F(k u ,5, husITUS))/ ln(F(ki , hos,ITus)) + ln((yus/ F(kus, liusITUS))/(y,:/F(ki , hiIT,:))), where y and k stanel for ouLput per worker anel capital per worker, respectively. By ,~:onstrudion, the snm in the right hanel size has to he eqnal to the left hand sÍze. 'rhe latt.er is the ratio of US GDP per worker to COU11- Lry i's GD1) per 'worker. The lirsL expression to thc right is the portioll of GDP diHel'f'.llce explained only by tariffs. vVe use our production function to measure cHltpnt, \vith the respective factors 01' prodndion, bnt we give to eountry; the tarifIs observecl in the USo Thc second expression gives the residual diflérence 01' output - artel' accOlmting for trade poliey - expIained hy hllman capital dispariLies. The third expresslon gives l.he residual dilTerence- aftel' accoullting for trade and educational disparities- explained by physical capital. Th" expression in the very bottom is Lhe residual TFP elitIercnce, iL is that part of TFP disparity which is not explainecl by tracle policy. 10 3 Data and calibration To assess h, we use a standard Mincer function of schoolillg, 01' the fOl'ln h = e08 . Follmving Psacharopoulos (199/1), we set. t-he return of schooling to q) =:: 0.099. \!Vc used data OH the average edllcational atlainment 01' 1.he population aged 15 year8 and over, takell from Barro and Lee (2000)4. \!Ve use the Penn-\Vorld Tnblet'i (PWT) dala for output per workcr. The physical capital series is construded with real investment. data from the P\!VT' usÍl1g the PerpetuaI Inventory l\Jethod. 'lhe inibal capital stock, ]{o, was approxÍmated hy ](0 = Io/[(l + .17)(1 +- 17,) - (1 - â)], where lo Ís the initial investmenL expenditure, 9 i8 the rate of technological progress and n 18 Lhe growth raLe oI' the populaLion. In t,his calculaLion it is assmned that alI economies were in a balanced gTOIvth pat-h aI, time zero, so that j j L_j = (1 -+ (1 -+lo· nr- gr- \Ve use thc same depreciation rate for alI economies, which was calculated from lJS data. \!Ve employed the capit.al slock a1. market Plices, invcst.ment at Inarket prices, I, as well as the law of lllOtioll of capital to estimat.e the implicit. depreciation rate according to: From this calculation, wc obtaincd â = 3.5% per year (average of the 19502000 period). To minimize Lhe impact of economic Dllctna1.ions we uscd the average investment of the first fíve years as a mcasure of lo. \!Vhen data was availnble we starLed this procedure taking 1950 as 1,he iniLial. year iH mder Lo reduce the efied of I(o in the capital stock series. 4 Data ,vere interpoJated (in levels) to fit an annual frequency when necessary. II Trade pnlicy is assessed with many alternalive data sources. '\Te flrst uscd, for i,he mid 19(;0's and mid U)80's, data from individual country studies. In Lhe finlt ca3e we nsed data from Balassa (1971) which constrnded, for a very limited number of countries, series of efIective rate 01' protection. For tbe seeond period we nsed data from Feneira anel Rossi (2001) ror Braz i! , Gonzalez-Vr~ga auel l\10nge (1995) for Costa Rica, Harrison (1994) for Ivory CoasL, anel vVorkl BalJk (Um3) for Tbailand. In 11.11 cases these mensures 01' proted;ioni~m \vere converted into T-equivalent terrns. vVe also Hsed \\Torld Bank(200G) data on avcrage tariff rates (unweighted). Althongh nominal tariff is a 'worse rneasure of protedionisnl than efTeetive raLe 01' proteetion, in the presellt case it has the advantage of being available for a large number 01' connLries. We interpret the large economy in steady state to be the U8; hence, we replicaLc Lhe standard calibration of tbe AnlCl'ican economy in dosedRBC models USil!.g f(k) ~= [Llkü. FoUowing NIPA figures for capital's sharc in l1RtÍonal income, we also match ê'f leaves frecduHl in choosing impodant, HS '''y', Ct a 1/3 This pins down the average = and O'/J. Q, but These parameters are particularly the quantitative effects of aU trade-l'elated phenomena, for low k, are bound to bc larger with a big spread (li/) ---- na, anel with a lower i, given Q. If bot-11 industl'ies requirc very different capital labor raLios, there is nmch to he gained from trade, as each cOlUlLry can specialize strongly on the industr.\- whosc demand is dosest to their endO\vlnent. We choose (V(L) C1!b anel i so that expol't.s cannot amount t.o more than hal1' ot' output, anel so tha!', for ~m\r one 01' Lhe 20 richest eonntries in the world in laRG, the LotaI gaius t'rom Lracle (the clifference between 12 T = ex) anel T = O) are ê1,t most 1% of toLal outpUL. This leads to ,../ = 1/2, eLa = 0.258 anel Ob = OAOS. Hesnlts are robust to varÍatíons of these values within rcasonable bounds. 4 Results "Ve find that for many countries the effect of trade polícy ís negligible, because they have low tarifIs, 01' because they are relatively wealthy compared to Lhe USo Similarly, for many extremely poor countries, the eflects of tarifis are large compareci to their own lo"v income, but only fi. very smaU fraction of their productivity difference with respect t.o the US, which is also very large. Ncvertheless, for some middle inconw economies with high tariff ratcs, Lhe effects are significant; in some cases, enough to at.trihute to protectionism one thircl of t;heir TFP disaclvant.age, 01' more. Tablcs 1 anel 2 show eompariSOl1Swith Lhe lJS for some cOlLnLries in Lhe mid 1960's and mid 1980's. The column labellecl li shows log-diflerences in output relRtive to Lhe tiS, anci the columns labelleel 8, k, 7 and 8 are the portioll of those log-differences t.hat cau be at.tributed to schooling, capit.al, protectionism anel produd,ivit,y, respectively. They should, of course, adel up to the value shown in column li, as saicl belore. The last COIUlIlll measures the proportion of t.otal residual (7 + 8) explained by tariff dístortions aloue. Table 1: Differences in output relative to t.he US, mid 1960's y S I" 1.. , 8 ,/(T+8) Chile 1.15 0.207 0.336 0.OG8 0.5,12 11.1% Bn'czil 1.18 0.326 0.497 0.058 0.299 16.3(/;) Pabstan 2.79 0.431 l.'ct61 0.027 0.870 3.1% Philippines 1.13 0.249 0.9H 0.022 O.GO'! d.d/o y .., k: , 8 ,/(, + 8) ') r'O'1 ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- Costa Rica 1.25 fJ.:329 0.66 0.04:3 0.216 lG.5% Brazil 1.07 0.'135 0.438 0.077 0.121 38.8% Ivory Coast 2.62 0.46 1.81 0.061 0.287 17.0% Th"jla,nd 2.()Ll 0.339 0.793 0.0:32 0.871 L7~;{) \Vé ean see that pl'oductivity 108s due Lo tarifls is significanL in SOlne cases, especially for the middle-income eonnLries. In Brazil in the 1980's, T explains ahnoRt ,10% oi' the TFP diflerence 'ivith respect to the lTS, vvhich is llot surprising as Brazil in Lhe period was one of the closest eeonomy in Lhe "vorld. In other cases as Costa Rica, Ivory Coast anel Chile in the 1960's, protection also have relatively large etTects 011 prodllctivity gap. or coursc, it carmot explain the bulk of per worker income difference in a given lllmnent, but the en~'ct OH TFP is sizable. Table 3 bdow presents results also for mid 1980's now l1sing \iVorld Bank data on aVt'l'il,ge tarifI rates. AR saicl before, this serics lIas the advantage 01' being available for a large munher or countries. Table :3: Diíferences in output rclative to l,he US, mid 1980':-; (World Bank tariff data) + 8). y .s k ..,, 8 Argentina 0.66 0.2 L1O 0.2/fLl 0.007 0.172 ,1.1% Banglade:-;h 2A4 0.50G 1.001 0.054 0.885 5.8% Brazil 1.07 0.'1:31 0.'138 0.018 0.18·c! 9.1 C;~) Colombia 1.24 0.372 0.512 0.012 0.:345 3.2% India 2.59 OA26 1.069 0.0;52 1.041 ~1.7% Mauritius 1.:3G 0.330 0.575 0.012 0.,,140 2.6% Mexico 0.70 0.:340 0.287 0.004 0.074 5.1% Pakistan 2.27 0.505 0.9 l:3 0.0:36 0.785 ,1.'1% Tnnisia 1.12 OA42 OA74 0.007 0.203 :3.1% Venezuela 0.85 0.:319 0.:3:39 O.OOU 0.187 ·'1.5% L T/(T . . The countries above were purposely chosen due to the larger effect of T. However, even m these cases Lhe impaeL of trade barrlcrs were noL 1,00 sizable. Only in Brazil it explains something dose to 101)() 01' the TFP gap. In other cases, sueh as Bangladesh, tariH~"l ~I'Iexico anel Incha, the observcd average \vere Lhe cause 01' 5% of the TFP difierence. l'dost. of the rclevant cases were Inidle-income economies in Latin America and Asia, in which measured tariffs "vere higher. In aU OECD countries, as expected, t11e impad was dose to zero: trade clue to compara tive aclvantage is not the main reason for them to trade, so 1,hat ou1' rnodel cannot capLnre thc cos1, 01' Lrade harricl"s. In vcry poor economies the measured impact was also small. There are Lwo reasons we ca.Il conjeeture for the impact of T t.o bc relat.lve snlall in the above table, although llot irrelevant in mau}' cases. One is that 15 • this mensure under-estimate the degree of protection. For iwstance, it does 1101, take inlo accOlmt the fact that in the mid 1980's non t.rade barriers such as cotas, li(:ensing 01' outright ban on the import of specific prodncts were \'lideiy used anel 1110st probably were more important for trade protection 1,ha11 tariffs, J:n t.he llrst two tables those fa.dors \vere taken into aCcollnt, at least partially. Moreover, even the tariffs in the World Bank data set seems too low. F'elTcira andllossi (2003) sl1mv Umt in Brazil, in Lhis period, avcrage tarilT was doser to 100%) than 47%, the mnnber in lhe vVorld Bank database. Ir we redo t he above exercise usíng the formeI' value ínstead of the later, we find that T i8 nhle lo explain almost 30% of the TFP gap. Moreover, inslead of onIy expIainillg 2.2%, of the output per worker difIerence with respect to the D.S., it now explaius 5.8%. Ir t.his is a general pattern of ta1"i[[· undermeasnrelnent, re~mlt.s in Table 3 would be very diiferent. A second possible reason for lhis resuU is Lhe fact that we were usmg very conservative calibration, one that tends to reduce the gains from trade. So itmight be the case that for diHcrent. values of those that :lncreasf~ 00. and C'Ib - particularly Lhe difIerence heb;veen lhern - we came up wilh larger TFP losses. This, however, is not the case unless we use very unreasonable pararnet.er \'1:1111es. Fbr instance, wit.h that still generate ("0 = 00. and n:b equal to 0.2 anel OAG7 (valnes 1;:3)), T would explain 4A%, 6A% anel 10.1%, of TFP difrerence of Argentina, Bangladesb anel Brazil, respedively. Those w~1ues are very dClse to tho8e displayed on Tahle :3. Finally, results when nsing 2000 data. found that in almost no case the ejTect of T i'l far from zero. In this case barriers to trade were found to bc irreleva.nt as most conntries experienced major trade liberalization after the mid 1980's. CHUCUUy, protection i8 focnsed in fcw, albciL key, sectors bnt this does not show up in the data among othc1' reaSOll:::l because tariH" is not the maln illstrumcnt u:sed. This is ln accord "viU1 Hodrik (77) LhaL i-U·gllCS that the gains from the current trade negot.iations, in tcrms of outpnt, are probably suml1 as most cconomies a.re now relaLively OpCIl. \Ve can also e:stiniate t-he output C08t 01" barriers Lo trade. \Ve use the foHowing fonnula: In this expression, ''.Te re-estimaLe country i ouLput with tiS tarifI in pInce of its own. It gives the measured gain 01" output if country i had its observed factor:-; of procluction but American tariffs. The gaills, in perccntage terms, are presenLed below 17 • Thble Li: Outpnt gains frorn "lrade" refonn Yin Mid 1980's I" .YIT* Chile G.9% Costa Rica 4.:3% 13razil 5.8S1;) Brazil 7.6% Pakistan 2.7% Ivory Coast 6.2?1() Philippines 2.1~~1 Thailand 3.2% l\1íd 1960's According; to Table 4, Brazil if its eflective mte 01' lU the eighties v!Ould be 8 percent richel' protection \vere considerably smaller. Although no!' enongh to dose t.he gap to the US OULpllt. - GDP per \vorkel' of Brazil was one third 01 that of lhe US in Lhe perioel - this is no small mnnber. Like,vise, fig11res for Chile, Ivory Coast and Costa Rica \vere relevant. In these cases Lhe static gain 01' eliminaLing lmrriel's to trade would increase hy 5S'{) 01' rnore outpu1. per vlOrker. 01' course, as we could expect given 1'esults of T,'1.b1e 3, the rneasure gains nsillg World Bank dRta are smaller. For the OECD countries(1,8 a matter 01' fact, for a majority of countries - the estimated gains are dose t.o zero. However, in t,hose cases ívere average tarijIs \vere relatively large, such as Bangladesh anel Indin, their reduction to US tariff leveis would imply gains of 5% 01' per wOl'ker GDP. 5 Conclusion In 1.his papel' \ve presented evidence tha1. barriers to I.rade were impOl't.an1. fador impairing lhe Pl'Odllctivity o[ less developed countries in the recent pasto In some cases it explained a sízable parI. of TFP dífference wiLh respect to Lhe leadillg cconomy. l\!Ioreovel', Lhe onLput cos(, 18 ma)r also he l'elevant. , The ütd that in mauy cases Lhe cosI, of trade halTiel's were estimaLed to he sIllall may be either an indication of data. problems, \vhich are \vell know in the trade lield - larifr is not aIways a precise mensure of baniers to trade - or may reHect the fact lhat protectionislll is not too hannflll nowadays. 01' Um,t an ag,g,TegaLe model sl1ch as OUI'::; are no!' abJe Lo capture the l"nll eHed of sophisticate protection measures v/ideIy useel today, such as export subsidy OI' anti-duping mensures. The methoelology we use does not capture lhe ütcl that barriers to lraele elo afiect investment decisions anel so capital stocks, son1.ething \ve have shown in onr previous paper (H~lTeira anel Trejos (200G)). In this sense, lhe current exercise is limiteel as it takes stocks as given but does not consieler lhat, if it. were noto for lrade restrictions, they would be cOllsidenl,hly la.rger. llence, re;omlts hcre can be seen as a lower bounel of the eosts 01' banires to lrade. References [1] Balassa, 8.,1971. "The 8tnlct'U're of Protect.ion m DE,ve!oping Coun(TÚS," 'J'he Johns IJopkins Press, Baltiulore. [2] CordeIl, \IV. , 1971. "The elTects of lrade on Lhe raLe of g,Tovv"t.hl!, in Bhagwati, Jones, Mundell e Vanek, Trade, Bala'nc6 of Payments anti GnJ7Dth, (NOl'Lh-HoUand), 1 17-1A:3. [:3] FelTeim, P. G and L..110.'>8i Jr, 200:3. "New Evidcnce ou Trade Liberal- ization aml Produdi vily Growth," Inf:eT1wíionalBconomic Revicw 44, 1:3S:3-1A07. U) .. I Hl Ferreira, P.c. Hnel A. Trejos ,2006. "On the Long-rnll Effects of Barriers t.o Trade." F'úrthcoming, Interrwt'ional Economic Revicw. [r.] Gonzalez-Vega anel R. l\iJonge, 1995. "Econonl'Ía Pol[t'Íca, Protec·· . . .u (~·.'.()·11.1·"·,'7',.,(·) Y. I,1l"J'' (:]'t"ll,r'(,>., , I "ta R L··..'"" \Inj (') " . , (8 <'tIl ,T()"'(' q c",," ..>', (1 .. oct o> .c. 'H , ·I·ô(l .. F1.·.1('".,c,, A',,< .' c. ,-"tC·it·" "1111" de Celltromnérica). [G] Hall,H. anel C. Jones, 1999. "\Vhy Do Some Countries Proeluce 80 Much More Output per 'VVorker Than Others?," (JuaTtcTly Jowrnal of Economic·~, 114, 8:j-11G. [7] Harrisj)n, A., 1996. "Openness anel GTovvth: a Time-Series, CrossConlltl'y Analysis for Developing Conntries," Jolt'l'na{ of Deudopment Economics, ·'18, 419- 147. L [8] Klenmv, P. J. anel A. Roelriguez-Clare, 1997. "The neoclassical revival in gTüwLh economics: bas it gone too far?," in Ben S. Bernanke anel Julio .T. Rotemberg, eds, NBER AlacrDf:conom'Íc8 AnnLlal 19.97 (Cmnbridge, MA: 'lhe MIT Press), n-103. [9J ldankiw, N. G., 1995. "The GrmOl,rth of Natiolls." Bmoking Paper8 on Economic Actiuity 1: 275<~2t:;. [lOJ Mankiw, N. C., Romer, D. anel D.Weil., 1992. "A ConLribution 'Ih The Empirics 01' Economic Grmvth." Quar'tt:rly JOIlT1wl of Ecolwlnic8 107 (May): 407- l:n, L [lIJ Prescot L, K, H)98. :'Neeeled: a Total Facto!' Prodnctivit,Y Theory," Intenwtirl1lal Economic Rt:vú:w, 39: 525-552. 20 FUNL'AÇ.\OGETUUO VARGAS BIBLIOTECA MARIO HENRIQUE SIMONSEN , [12] Psncharopoulos, Go, 1994. "Heturns to InvestmcnL in Edncation: A Global Update," World Devf:loprncnt, 22(9): 1325-13,j:t [13] 'll-ejos, Ao, 1992"On Lhe Short-Rull Dynamic Eflects of Compara tive Ad vantage 'Jj.'aete ," mmmscripL, UniversiLy of Pel1nsylvalliao [1~1] Ventura, .1, 1n970 "CrO\vth anel Interdependence", (Juo/lúTly Jonnlal of Economú~s, 112, 57-8 e1. [15] vVorld Bank (199~~) [16] vVorld llank(2005) 21 FUNDAÇÃO GETULIO VARGAS BIBLIOTECA ESTE VOLUME DEVE SER DEVOLVIDO A BIBLIOTECA NA ÚLTIMA DATA MARCADA N.Cham. P/EPGE SA F383m Autor: Ferreira, Pedro Cavalcanti. Título: Measuring the TFP costs of barriers to trade. 385151 1111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111 102443 000385151 1111111111111111111111111111111111111 •