.N~ 174 LOCAL CONCAVIFIABILITY OF PREFERENCES . AND DETERMINACY DF EQUILIBRIUM MARIO RUI PASCOA E SERGIO RIBEIRO DA COSTA WERLANG MAIO DE 1991 l LOCAL CDNCAVIFIABILITY DF PREFERENCES AND DETERKlNACY DF EQUlLIBRIlDI By "Mario Rui Pascoa University of Pennsylvania and Sergio Ribeiro Da Costa Werlang Fundacao Getulio Vargas, Rio De Janeiro Keywords: Concavifiability of Preferences; Rectifiability of Demand; Local Uniqueness of Equilibrium Prices We are thankfuI to Beth Allen, Bernard Cornet, James Dow, Andreu MasColell, Hugo Sonnenschein and Bi11 Zame for helpful conversations and to Paulo Monteiro for pointing out some errors in an earlier version of this papcr. are also indebted to Eduarda Figueiredo for the translation of A1exandroff's (1939) paper. \Je i ABSTRACT In this paper we consi.der strictly convex monotone continuous complete preorderings on function. nf+ that are local1y representable by a concave utility By Alexandroff's (1939) theorem. this function is twice dífferentiable almost everywhe~e. We show that if the bordered hessian determinant of a concave utility representation vanishes on a nul1 set. then demand is countably rectifiable, that is, except for a null set of bundles, it is a countable union of manifolds. C1 This property of consumer demand is enough to guarantee that the equilibrium prices of apure exchange economy will be locally unique. for almost every endowment. We give an example of an economy satisfying these conditions but not the Katzner (1968) - Debreu (1970. lq72) conditions. ~~00th~e~~ I J 1 1. Introduction In the past twenty years economic theorists have devoted a considerab1e effort to the issue of local uniqueness of equilibrium prices. paper Debreu (1970) showed that apure exchange economy with In a seminal m consumers whose demand functions are smooth is such that, for almost every endowment, equilibrium prices are locally unique. demand functions goes to + IX) If, in addition, the norm of the .as the boundary of the price simplex is approached, then the set of equilibrium prices associated with each endowment is compact, and therefore, local uniqueness implies finiteness. Smoothness of demand is a very strong condition. Katzner (1968) considered strict1y quasiconcave twice-continuously differentiable utility functions, forwhich the marginal utilities are always strictly positive and the indifference hypersurfaces do not intersect the boundary of the positive iff the bordered hessian of the utility function does not vanish at x. Under Katzner's assumptions, th1s condition 1s satisfied on an open dense subset of consumption bundles and on a corresponding open dense subset of ful1 measure of prices and incomes. Katzner's condition isequivalent to saying that the indifference hypersurface has nonvanishing Gaussian curvature at x. A more general result by Debreu (1972) established that for preferences of class demand is smooth at curvature at x x iff the indifference hypersurface has nonzero Gaussian (see Debreu (1976) also, where it is shown that smoothness of demand does not require the existence of a 2 C utility representation with no criticaI point). Differentiability almost everywhere is therefore the most that can be expected under very general assumptions. However this is an interesting 2 property on1y if one can use it to infer the nature of demand from observed reactions to price changes. Therefore we need to guarantee that most quantity variat10ns do not occur on a negligible set of pr1ces. This argument motivated Rader (1973) to introduce the condition that demand shou1d map nu11 sets of prices and 1ncomes into nu11 sets of quantities - condition (N). estab1ished that differentiabi1ity a1most everywhere together (N) guarantee that, for a1most ~1ith He condition alI endowments, equi1ibrium is 10ca11y unique (a1though the set of endowments having infinite equilibria might be dense). Rader (1973) showed a1so that demand is different1able a1most everywhere in prices if the utility function is concave and demand is continuous and 10ca11y Lipschitzian in 1ncome. He also estabIished that if demand 1s uniformly Lipschitzlan income and the incrementaI ratio of pr1ces to quantity 1s bounded from below, then condition (N) is satisf1ed. In a later paper, uti11ty function is twice d1fferentiab1e and condition (N) holds if uti11ty 1s ana1ytlc (derivatives of a11 orders exist and are 10cally subject to a common bound). K1einberg (1980) studied the issue of generic finiteness of equi1ibria using the weaker concept of approximate differentiabi1ity of demando cons1dered strictly quasi-concave utl1ity functions of class Vu 15 approximate1y differentiable. c1 He for which In additlon, he imposed some contlnulty and boundedness condltions on the approximate derivative of Vu to guarantee that the demand function 1s approximately differentiable on the comp1ement of an at most countable set of prices and incomes. Kleinberg showed that for th1s c1sss of demand functions equi1ibria is locally un1que for almost every endowment. _____ J 3 Tha purpose of this paper is to examine what can be the contribution of concavifiabílity of preferences to the issue of local uniqueness of equilibrium prices. An assumption on local concavifiability is not too strong and is already implied by Katzner's (1968) conditions. (1985) showed (Proposition 2.6.4), if a strictly convex In fact, as Mas-Colell C2 preference has indifference hypersurfaces with nonvanishing Gaussian curvature and can be representable by a 2 C compact convex set K there is a utility function with nocritica1 point, then for any point where the restriction to 2 C utility representation with no criticaI K is differentiability strict1y concave (i.e., has a negative definite hessian matrix on K). Ye consider monotone continuous complete preorderings that are locally representable by a concave utility function u, which might not be differentiable throughout the interior of the effective domain. 1:1 wt:ll kllOll/ll lhat the funct:ion u However, it is áifferent1able almost everywhere on the interior of its effective domain and that the partia 1 functions admit everywhere one-sided derivatives. Much is also known about the second derivative of a concave function. Alexandroff (1939) showed that a concave function admits almost everywhere a 2nd order expansion. Moreover, he introduced extended partial derivatives which lie within the one-sided derivatives of the partial functions and showed that these extensions are almost everywhere differentiable, with remainder converging uniformly on the choice of the extensions and with derivatives given by the matrix of the quadratic form in the 2nd order expansion. This result was our main motivation to write this paper. If, in addition to local concavifiability we assume that the bordered hessian matrix of the local utility representation is nonsingular almost rr J 4 everywhere, then, we can claim that, from the point of v1ew of geometric measure theory, the range of the demand function behaves like a c~ manifold. In fact, except for a null set of bundles, demand 1s a countable union of submanifolds. C1 In the terminology of geometric measure theory, the demand range is countably rectifiable. We show that this property of demand 1s enough to guarantee that, in apure exchange economy, equ11ibrium prices are local1y unique, for a1most every endowment. We give an examp1e of a 2 x 2 pure exchange transferab1e ut11ity economy satisfying our assumption, but not the Katzner-Debreu smoothness conditions, and for which the set of equilibrium prices is finite, for almost every endowment. It is interesting to notice that the property of rectifiabi11ty of demand that we have estab1ished is weaker than Rader's (1973) conditions for generic local unl\{uefl~sli>. In fact, under rectifiahillty thê cüüditiü~ _'L. __ ,","CLt.. demand map null sets into nu11 sets is sat1sfied but demand is not differentiable in almost every price and income. The comparison of our results with Kleinberg's (1980) is more subt1e, s1nce he requires the demand function to be on1y approx1mately different1able except on a countab1e set and his assumptions on preferences do not involve local concavifiabi1ity. However, K1einberg (1980) assumes differentiability of the uti1ity function, which is an assumption that we have d1spensed with. 2. RECTIFIABILITY OF DEKAND 2.1 Preliminar1ties lRn and a preference re1ation R is a complete -+ x -y if x R y and y R x and 1et x P y if The consumpt1on set 1s preordering on r -n K+. Let 5 x R Y but not y R x. Ye say that a preference relat10n x + (l-À) y P y, À implies x P y. when x R y A function if and only if x IRn (ii) strictly convex if x R y + O < À ~ I and (iii) monotone if x» y nf+ continuous if it graph is closed on implies for any :nf+ ... u: u(x) ~ IR 1s a utility representation for n-l d mapp1ng int â The demand set 1s A preference relation compact convex set for R. R the demand function for ~ into m 1 - X (where p d(p,y) - Y and dimensional simplex), satisfying d(p,y) R z. R u(y). Given a strictly convex preference relation is a function R 1s (1) n 1 d(int â - X p z â S n-l R 1s the y-> I~). R is locally (strictly) concavifiable if for any K~ ~ there is a (strictly) concave representation By Alexandroff's (1939) theorem, this function ~ ~ is twice- differentiable almost everywhere and the hessian matrix, where 1t exists, is a negative semi-definite matrix. this theorem. 2.1.2. Alexandroff's theorem For technica1 reasons we want to think of alI concave functions as defined throughout domain. nf and taking the va1ue u and by Denote by int(dom u) A proper concave function subset outside of the effect1ve The extended real-valued function obtained thisway 1s ca11ed a proper concave function. function -~ D of int(doro u) of measure zero; moreover, dom u the effective domain of the the respective interior. u on Df is differentiab1e on adense and the complement of u D on int(dom u) is a set is actually continuously differentiable on D (see Rockafellar (1970) 25.5) r 6 A1exandroff (1939) established that a proper concave function 15 a1so twice-differentiable almost everywhere on domain int(dom u). u Df on Since the D of the first derivative may have an empty interior, we should be more precise and recall the exact statement of A1exandroff's theorem. Let u(xi;x_ ) : IR ~ IR u i by setting alI variables but u~ (x ;x. ) i 1 (-c:o) xi be the proper concave function obtained equa1 to and the 1eft derivative u:(Xi;X_ i ) the effective domain of this function and ui The right deriva tive are well defined throughout of the u u:(xi;X_ i ) S u~ (Xi;X_ ) (see i A1exandroff (1939) defined an extended partia1 Rockefe11ar (1970) 23). derivative • x_i E -Il-1. JK as any function satisfying the inequa1ity u:<Xi;X_ i ) S ui(x) S u~(xi;X_i)' where coincides with the partia1 derivative x - (xi;X_ i ). 8u (x) 8x Note that when it exists. i Iheorem (Alexandroff): a1most everywhere on for any direction where L(S)/S y E the extended partia1 derivative int(dom u) ui i5 differentiab1e and at any point X of differentiabi1ity, Df, we have converges to zero uniform1y on the directions independent1y of the choice of the extension H(x) - [Vul(x) ... Vun(x)~ ui' y and a1so Moreover. the matrix is uniquely determined, lndependent of the choice of the extens10ns and 1s a symmetric negative semidefinite matrlx. Actua11y, the matrix H(x) - [hik(x)] exists on1y at points where u once differentiab1e (see Alexandroff (1939) pp. 5 and 6) but not necessari1y is 1 7 at any such point. Furthermore, for any direction given by a normalized 21 y' H(x) Y coincides with the dlrectlonal second-derivative given b y 1im ( u ( x + sy) - u(x) - ~ L u (x) sYi)/5 2 By a 1 vector y, the quadratic for s~O l-i result due to Iessen (1929), in the case of a concave function, a d1rectional n L second-derivative is a usual second-der1vat1ve, that 1s, u(x+sy)-u(x)2 n n 2 i-i U1 (x)sYi-;hiK(x) YiYk - €S where €~O as s~O, uniformly on alI i-1 K-1 . d1rections y. Then, any concave function admits at almost everypo1nt x a r r second-order Taylor expans10n and the matrix of the quadratic form is the matrix H(x). IR2 Busemann and Fel1er (1935) had shown that a concave funct10n in admits directional second-der1vat1ves a1most everywhere 1n its effective doma1n. Alexandroff (1939) extended their result to an arbitrary f1nite dimension (in part 2 of his paper) and established the relation between the directionAl second-der{vativp.~ Rnn ~h~ d~riv~tives of the extended p~rti~l derivatives (in part 3 and 4 of his paper). 2.1.3. Rectifiabi1ity Recall that a function Lipschitzian if for any 18 Ln M-rectifiable if 1s said to be locally a E A there ex1st an open bal1 llf(x) - f(y) II constant M such that Denote by f: A ~ . n:F~nf :S M "x-yll, the Lebesgue measure in Ln(E) < ~ and n L - JIf.' for" any B (a) E. and a x,y E B (a). € We say that a set almost alI of E~ JIf E 1s contained in the un10n of the images of countably many loca11y L1pschitz1an function5 from DF to JIf. almost alI of sets. A set E~ n IR is said to be countab1y n-rectif1able 1f n L _ E is contained in the union of countably many rectifiab1e As we wil1 see next, from the point of view of geometric measure r 8 C1 theory, rectifiable sets behave like manifo1ds. Geometric measure theory can be described as differentia1 geometry genera1ized through measure theory to dea1 with maps and surfaces that are not smooth. n Denote by E I~ ba11 around a and a E Df; Df the Lebesgue measure on L with radius the set A 6. Let 86 (a) and by for any 6 < A~ nf. The approximate 1im sup of V(>o 3 >0 a if f def1ned on a 6 6. Conslder an extended real va1ued measurab1e function measurab1e set I~ A be a measurable subset of is'said to have density zero at such that the c10sed f a E at nf is deflned as ap 1im sup f(x) - inf B, x-+a where B - (t E De (x E A: f(x) > t} From the definition, if the set has dens1ty zero at a} A has density zero at a then ap lim sup f(x) - -~. It is immediate that if 1im sup exists then 1t 1s x -+ a equal to the approx1mate 1im sup. Sim1IarIy, zero at ap 11m inf f(x) - sup (t E IR: (x E A: f(x) < t} has density a}. Recall that a function Lipschitzian at funct10n at a f: A ~ a E f from A ~ n IR 1s said to be pointwise A if Um sup Ilf(x)-f(a)l!lIx-a~ <~. S1milarly, a x ... a nf ... nf is said to be approximate1y pointwise Lipschitzian ap 11m sup IIf(x) -f(a) !Ix-ali < ~. x ... a The foI1owing lemmas summarize the most important facts about E A 1f approximate1y Lipschizian functions. 9 temIDa 1 (Federer): if a function pointwise Lipschltzian on f: A ~ A then sets such that the restriction of nf ~ nr A is the countable union of measurab1e f to each set Is Lipschitzian and moreover Is approximate1y differentiab1e a.e. on A: f map nf L: ~ nr 1s approximately that Is, there existsa linear with ap 11m ~f(x) - f(a) - L(x-a)lI/l1x-all - O x'" a (for a proof see Federer (1969) 3.1.8). Remark f: A ~ IRn ~ Then, the range of a function nf whlch is approximate1y pointwise Lipschitzian is a countably rectifiable set. a countable cover of f(A) In f~~t. by bounded sets and each one is a rectiflab1e set, slnce the Lipschltzian restriction of f can be extended to the who1e preserving the Lipschitzlan constant (see Federer (1969». g: B C nf f: A ~ B ... ~IRn nr admits an approximate1y pointwise Lipschitzian restriction such that f(A) has fuII measure in g(B), then a function f: A ~ nf ... nr In fact, by !emma I, ~ A is nuI1 set, then A - co U C K-1 K f(B n C ) K g(B) is f. that is approximate1y pointwise Lipschitzian on A maps nu1I sets into nuI! sets, provlded B I~ Moreover, if a1so countably rectifiab1e through Lipschitzian restrictions of Lemma 2: on~ ~an tak~ such that n ~ m. is Lipschitzian and if flc K is a1so nu1! and f(B) - co u f(B n CK)· K-I Now we wlll estab1ish a result on the rectifiabiIity of the inverse of a differentiab1e function. r j 10 Proposition 1: 1et f and IR?; and taking values in measurable subset function. f'(a) suppose that the restriction of D admits the restriction of Let a nf g be functions defined on an open subsets of be a limit point of D. lf g f to f(D) f to a as an inverse is differentiable at a and is nonsingular, then b(b+s) -g(b) 11 ap 11m sup s .. O glf(D) Koreover. lf Ils~ D is a full measure subset of dom f then the above inequality holds as an equality. ftQ.Qí: Inverting the incrementaI ratio we have, ap Um sup Ilg(b+s) - g(b) 11111511 s .. O ~f(a+x)-f(a)1I - inf {t e IR: (x e(D-a): Ilxll I < -t} has density zero at a} ~fCa+x) -fCa) II - l/sup {t e IR: {x e (D-a): < t} Ilxll x"O :S IIxll a} ~f(a+x) -fCa) II ~f(a+x)-f(a)~ - l/ap 11m inf has denslty zero at l/11m inf x .. O IIx~ flD when the last inequality follows from the following set inclusion: ~f(a+x)-f(a)1I {t e IR: (x e(D-a): ~xll < t} has density zero at a}::> r 11 IIf(a+x) -f(a) II If < t}has density zero at a} ~xll (t e IR: (x e(dom f-a): D has full measure in dom f then these two sets are equal and the above inequaIity holds as an equaIity. To fin1sh the proof derivative at a Oh recal~ that for a mapping h at a point a, the ls equa1 to 1im inf li (Dh(a» -lrl w1th nonsingu1ar of the incrementaI ratio of h (see Federer (1969) p. 209). FlnaI1y, we present the results that allow us to think of a rectifiab1e set almost as a countable union of C1 manifolds. The Lipschitzian functions In the definition of a rectifiable set can bereplaced by 1 C functions due to the following lemma. Lemma 3: (Federer): f: A ~ a function Df ~ nF that ls approximately polntw1se Lipschitzian is such that for 1 C map than 1-( n g: 1K .... -m lK identical to f a.e. In A (o> O there exists a on a subset of A of measure greater (for a proof see Federer (1969) 3.1.16). Using this lemma, Federer established the fo110wing characterization of rectifiability. Lemma 4: in the definition of a rectifiable set Llpschitzian functions to be C1 o E one can take the diffeomorphisms on compact domains with disjoint images whose union coincides with (see Federer (1969) 3.2.18 and 3.2.29 E a1most everywhere. and Morgan (1988) 3.11) r 12 2.2. Ibe result 2.2.1. Tbeorem 1: if a continuous, monotone, strictly convex preference ~ re1ation R on is locally concavifiab1e and for each representat10n ~ the bordered hess1an matrix 1s singular only in a set of measure zero, then the- demand function every va1ue. d That is, n 1 e d(int A - x IR++). is approx1mately pointwise Lipschitzian for almost ap 1im sup d(PÓ Y) < (p,y) ~ (pO,y ) ~ for a1most every xo • d(p O,yO) In other words, by 1emma 1 and the remark in 2.1.3 demand 1s countab1y rectifiab1e and, by 1emma 4 in 2.1.3, except for a nu11 set of bundles, it 1s the union of countably many pairwise disjoint compact 2.2.2 1 C submanifo1ds. Proof of the Tbeorem Consider a countab1e cover of K ~ ~,R cube ~ by c10sed cubes. is represcntab1e by a concave uti1ity function criticaI point, by monotonicity of R. nonempty interior, since otherwise u with no For simpIicity, we assume that a proper concave function with effective doma in K. We assume that u K has poin~ise Lipschitzian for a1most every For the same reason, we w111 consider on1y the optima1 interior so1utions in K, since the boundary of K is a n-nu11 set. Let N be the nu11 subset of int K when u is not twicedifferentiable. x e int K\N, Let given by 6(x) is K would be irre1evant for the purpose of proving that demand is approximate1y va1ue. For each c10sed be the bordered hess1an determ1nant of u at ; _ .i 13 6(x) - u n (x) u nn (x) u (x) n o ... u (x) n Let CP be the nuIl subset of determinant int K\N where the bordered hessian 6 of u van18hes-. Let RP be the complement of CP on int K\N. Recall Debreu's (1972) decomposition of the demand function and adopt it to the case where dom Du g: x ... V u(x)/IIVu(x) 11 of g(x). is just a fuIl measure subset of and g(x) a The restriction the inverse of the function 1s the composition of p a: x be the vector of the first of the demand function d (g(u), u(x» ~nd n-1 to f: x ... (p,y) • (g(x),g(x)-x). ~ int K. p: (p,v) d -1 Let components (dom Du) This function 4 is f when (p,w(v}) e int â n-1 and m(v) - min p.z. u(z) g, Let and ã f v ~ be any extensions of g, a and f, respectively obtained using Alexamdroff's extended partial derivatives. The Jacobian determinant of ã n gn(x)/llvu(x) II , gn(x) _ u n where (x)/IIDu(x) 11) . n g (x) S'" J f(x) - J (fJoã) - pA ~S O on RP. J ã(x) - -6(x) g(x) (that is, The function fJ has the which 18 the inverse of the function - 6(x)u (x) /IIVu(x) II n 1s component of Now Vv(s) - IIVu(x) li, max u (z). pz m, x E int K\N n th 1s the Then J(a)(x) same Jacobian determinant as given by at n+2 and for J f(x) x - d(p,s). pA v Therefore O if and on1y 1f x E RP. r 1. 14 Now. by Proposition 1 in 2.1.3 above. for x oE o O O let (p ,y ) - f(x ) RP. ap lim sup d(p.y) < (1). where d Id -1 (dom Du). Since dom (p,y)"'(pO.yO) has fuH measure in int K we also have ap lim sup d(g'y) < (1), for (P.y) -+ (pO.y ) O O O O x and E RP. We have proven that the demand function is (p .y ) - f(x ) a- and we have RP approximately pointwise Lipschitzian on the inverse image of a full measure subset of int K. and RP is To complete the proof. notice that the countable union of the null complements of each set cube Ou RP in the respective K is a null subset of Q.E.D. ~ ~ Notice that the result still holds for a strict1y concave function which is differentiable almost everywhere and such that the derivative admits an extension f to the whole domain of u differentiable almost everywhere. (iH) (ii) f' so that (i) exists whenever f VU u Vu is itself exists and f' in the case when u admits almost-everywhere a second-order expansion and the matrix in this quadratic form coincides with fI. almost verywhere (as it 1s the case with a concave function). 3. Local Unigueness Consider a exchange economy with dj : int Iln-1 X 1R++'" endowment of the nf+ jth m consumers and be the demand function and consumer. n goods. w E ~ j Let be the We keep the demand functions fixed and parameterize an economy by an endowment vector w - (w1 •...• wm). Given w E n-l is an equilibrium price vector of the economy an element p E int Il nfl1l ++' m m w if I dj(p.p-wj ) - I wj ' Let E(w) be the set of equilibrium price j-l j-l vectors of the economy w. We say that equilibrium prices are locally unique r 15 if alI e1ements in Ibeorem 2: E(w) are iso1ated points of this set. If the demand functions dI"'. ,d of a11 consumers are m approximate1y pointwise Lipschitzian for a1most every demand bund1e, then the equi11brium prices are 1oca11y unique, for a1most every froof: Let F: U ~ nrm U - lnt  n 1 - x lR++ x vector. lR~m-1) and define the function as in Debreu (1970) by m F1(e) - d 1 (p'Y1) + where endo~~ent r m di (p,p-w) - 1-2 r W 1-2 1 u, peF1(e) - Y1' A1so, P is an equi1ibrium price vector -1 (P'Y1'w2 ,··· .wm) E F (w). We want to show that for a.e. w. every e e For F- 1 (w) 18 a is local1y iso1ated. Let us start by c1aim1ng that the range of m-n-countab1y rectifiab1e set (through Lipsch1tz1an restrictions of Let ~ K~1 E Mj be the full measure subset of M of disjoints images of jk Denote by Define N C1 its nu11 comp1ement in j N1 - diffeomorphic restrictions of ~. d1(p'Yl) E N1 } (w E IR~ : w - F(e), e - (P'yl'w2 •... ,wm) and in F F) which 1s the countable union - (w E ~: w - F(e). c - (P'y1.w2 •...• wm) and Nj ~ 1ff d . j 16 \le want to show that Nj and - IR~Mj jê N 1 j is a nu11 set. N1 - Now ~K~\ 1 where M1 - (w E ~: w E F(e). e - (P.y1.w2' ...• wm) and d1 (p'Y1) E MIl Mj - (w E ~: w E F(e). e - (P'Y1. w2'· ..• wm) and \le need to establish that dj (p •P owj) Mj (j E Mj l • j ,.. 1 0- 1 •...• m) 1s offull measure in llfID + . Now wE M 1 iff d1 (p'Y1) E M1 for any (P,Y 1 .w2 •... ,W ) E F -1 (w). that 1s, m -1 -1 (P'Y1) E d1 (M 1 ) n 11(F (w» - B1 where 1j is the jth projection mopping (app1ied in this case to E -1 (Mj )' n 'Yj (F dj m j~l n Similar1y. lR). -1 Let (w» - Bj. n B1- (x E IR : x - (P.pow i ), P and Bj1 - (x M- Then i ,.. 1. j i!i A i iff E nf: where x - E j1(Bj ), w i E n\l ( P 'Y1 ) ,P E j 1 (B) > j ' Y1 E IR+. A{ - Mj + L i"'j di(Bi> - j L A i,.. 1 i and ne, j A i for By the Brunn-Minkowski theorem (see Federer (1969). 3.2.4», for any nonempty sub sets di(Bji) - L A Aj )l/n, and B of n lR (not necessar11y of finite measure), we where. on the right-hand-side, at 1east the first term 1~ 1,..1 +~. So 1s mon - countab1y rect1fiab1e through i Mj 1s of fu11 measure in ~ and therefore the range of F F. To complete the proof of the theorem. notice that the set regarded as the un10n of countab1y many disjoint (by taking appropr1ate set differences). F(U) can be mon-rectifiab1e sets Now. by lemma 5 in ~ 2.1.3 (from Federer (1969», one can take the countably many Lipschitzian functions in the definition of each rectifiab1e set ~ to be 1 C diffeomorphisms DiK on 11 compact domains with disjoint images, whose union coincides with the rectifiable set alrnost everywhere. which is a Let N - F(U) \ KQ1 iê range l m-n-null set. F(u) \ N is such that Now, any endowment vector on w e F(u) \ N and any e1ement E(w) e e F-1(w) have neighborhoods respectively, that are homeornorphic under the restriction to DiK . w e F(u) \ N, Moreover, for each D this map iK determined, because the reetifiab1e sets are disjoint and the disjoint images. Then, for any O has a neighborhood neighborhood between 4. O P E(w) p and F -1 w e F(U) \ N, O e ow and Oe O, e C1 of some is uniquely D iK any price vector where there are no other e1ements of ls induced by has on1y 1 C -inverse function theorem, any element In fact, by toe isolated points. map Dlk' p maps have in E(w) E(w) (this through the one-to-one correspondence (w». AN EXAMPLE Here, we give an exarnp1e of apure exchange economy where utility functions are concave, but not differentiab1e, and we still have finiteness of equilibria, for almost every endowment. In this examp1e the set of endowments generating infinite equilibria is dense. Consider an economy with two eonsumers with the sarne cone ave uti1ity which i5 constructed so that an indifference curve is function on differentiable on1y at irrationa1 points. For each ~ e Q, let f n Notice that now f be the characteristlc function of the set f n is nondecreasing and has a jump at is nondeereasing, at any q n q . n e Q it has a jump of 18 magnitude 1/2 n and it 1s differentiable except at the rationals, with zero derivative. Now integrate f to obtain a convex increasing function. Since only a countable set of discontinuities it 1s Riemann 1ntegrable. f Let has g be such that. g(x) - xIO f(t)dt The derivative any irrat10nal x. g' exist& at every continuity point of Furthermore, at any rationa1 and g'(q ) - f(q +) - f(q ). + n n n Notice that g(ax + (1-a)y) ~ ~x f(t)dt + since f i8 nondecreasing and for g ~ f, we have that is, at g'(q) - f(q-) n n i8 strictly convex: (1-a)y lo f(t)dt, O < a < 1 we have ~x f(t)dt < aJ~ f(t)dt Now 1et h: IR++ ~ IR++ be defined by h(x) - g(1/x). The function h 1s decreas1ng, convex, differentiable only at irrationa1 points; it wi11 be used as an indifference" curve. Let the utility function be 2 u: lR++ ~ IR The preferences in this examp1e satisfy the assumptions of theorems 1 and 2 but not the smoothness conditions of Katzner (1968) or Debreu (1972)-(1976). In fact the bordered hessian determinant of u, at (x ,x ) E 1 2 (~Q) x ~ 15 '" 19 o o 1 - h" (x ) 1 o 1 and h"(x ) - -- g"(l/x ) 1 2 1 xl Now AIexandroff's extended partial derivative g" is the derivative of the and therefore g' - f + 2 g" vanishes 1 . 3 o, for any xl and the bordered hessian determinant is nonzero on the full measure identically on its domain x, E ~Q set (~Q) x ~Q. Then h"(x ) - l f( /x l ) > ]R. Let us examine the demand functions and the equilibria of this econorny. implying except at prices associated with points where h is not differentiabIe and these prices are elements oí the subdifferentials and generate demand x 2 - Y-Plqn P2 lle have determined completely the form of the demand function. It is easy to see that when the endowment vector w 1 For (w ,w ) 1 2 1s irrational, then the equilibrium prlce ratio 1s equal to w 1 is such that -h' (w / ). l 2 rational, the set of equ11ibrium price ratios is the interval [-h~(wl/2)' -h:(wl / 2 )]· That is, aImost every endowment generates finite equiIibrium prices but the set of endowments giving rise to infinite equilibrium prices 1s dense. r · ..! 20 References A1exandroff, A.D. (1939): nExistence of the Second Differentia1 of a Convex Function A1most Everywhere in its Domain and Some Related Properties of Convex Surfaces" (Russian), Leningrad State University, Annah 37, Mathematical Series, 6, pp. 3-35. Debreu, G. (1970): "Economies with a Finite Set of Equilibria", Econometrica 38 . . Debreu, G. (1972): "Smooth Preferences", Econometrica 40. Debreu, G. (1976): "Smooth Preferences: Federer, H. (1969): A Corrigendum", Econometrica 44. "Geometric Measure Theory", Springer-Verlag Katzner, D. (1968): nA Note on the Differentiabi1ity of Consumer Demand Functions" , Econometrica 36, No. 2, pp 415-418. K1einberg, N. (1980): "Continuous Economies with a Finite Set of Equi1ibria", Journal of Mathematica1 Economics. Mas-Colell, A. (1985): "The Theory of General Economic Equi1ibrium", Cambridge University Press. Morgan, F. (1988): "Geometric Measure Theory: Press A Beginner's Guide" , Academic Rader, T. (1973): "Nice Demand Functions" , Econometrica 4. Rader, T. (1979): Economics. "Nice Demand Functions 11", Journal of Mathematica1 Rockafel1ar, T. (1970): Sard, A. (1958): No, 2. Convex Ana1ysis" , Princeton University Press "Images of CriticaI Sets", Annals of Mathematics, Vol. 68, jOlJlloU.\c,.:AO GETULIO VARGAS .uw.Ol IÇA MARtO HK.~WQUE SlMONSr:. r ENSAIOS ECONÔMICOS DA EPGE (a partir do nº 100) 100. JUROS, PREÇOS E DíVIDA P~3LICA VO~U~lE I: ASPECTOS TEÓRICOS - Marco Antonio C. Martins e Clovis de Faro - 19a7 (esgotaoo) 101. JUROS, ?REÇOS E D11..'IDM PÚBLICA VOLIJr-:E 11: A ECO~Cr':IA 8r:U\SILGRA - ::'~~7VSS - Ar.-:onic Sa1azar P. arandão, ClÓJis ~ r::>ro e ~8rco,ll.• C. j'''ertir6 - 1767 (e=~1.l-'o) 102. MACROECJNOHIA KALECKIA~A - Rubens Penha Cysne - 1987 103. O PR~MIO JJ DÓL~R ~O ~ERCA~O PARALELO. O 5UBFATURA~ENTO DE EXPORTAÇ~ES E O SUPERFATURA~~NTO DE IMPCRTAÇdES - Fernando de HQ1anda Barbosa - Rubens Panh3 Cyene e Marcos Costa rlola~d3 - 19B7 (esgotado) 104. BRAZILIAN EXPERIENCE WITH EXT~RNAL DEBT AND PROSPECTS FOR GRC~THFernando de Hol.anda 8a:-bosa 2nd íJ~an'Je1 S2!lCn8Z de. La Cal - 1987 (esgCJ:sc:» 105. KEYNES ~!A SEDIÇÃO DA t:5COLHri PÚ8LICA- A,-,tonio ~·j'.da Silveira-1987(es;:::'a:o) 106. O TEORU1,n. ::JE FROaENIUS-PER~[ji\ - Carlos Ivan Simoflsen Leal - 1537 107. POPULAÇ~O BRASILEIRA - Jess~ Montello-19B7 (escotedo) 108. MACR.O~Cm~O:'lIA - CAPíTULO VI: "DnlM!DA POR MOEDA:: A CURIJA U,jlT - Mario H9nrique Simonsen e Rubens Penha Cysne-1987 (esgotado) 109. MACROECOi'·jOf"1IA - CAPíTULO VII: "DGiP.NDA P~REGA.DA E·A CURVL\ :S~: - Mario Henrique Sií.lons8n e .RL!bens Penha Cysne - 1987 - (esgotacC)) 110. MACROECONOMIA - MODELOS DE EQUILíaRIO AGREGATIVO A CURTO ~~~ZD - Mario Henrique Simonsen e Rubens Penha Cysne-19B7 (esgotado) ll1. - •• - lHe. _ .... , ' _ .... - ,.. ... OHYr..~l.HI·~ -,-, I I" I r"'\ " ~ ""l"" ,.... f i ' - rUUI'IJUM~~UI\l':'; n r- ur r:--" I I T T"'" 1\1 ..JULUI..L.UI"4 r r"''' I r r- n 1..J'-.Ji~L...L-1 T C' l..J n C" '-'I r,,"~ C" C Ufl'IL---..J c: ' . _=:-g!8 Ribeiro da Costa Werlang e TOf:1my Chir.-Chiu ian - 1987 (esgotado) 112. PREÇOS líqUIDOS (PREÇOS DE VALOR ADICIONADO) E SEUS DETERr1!NANTES; DE PRODUTOS SELECIONADOS, NO PERíODO 1980/1º Semestre/1986 - Raul Ekermdn - 1987 113. EMPRrSTIMOS BANCARIOS E SALDO-MrDIO: O CASO DE PRESTAÇÔES - Clovis de Faro - 1988 (esgotaQo) 114. A DINAMICA DA INFLAÇAo - Mario Henrique Simonsen - 1988 (esgotado) 115. UNCERTAINTY AVERSION AND THE OPTIMAL CHOISE DF PORTFOLIO James - Dow e S~rgio Ribeiro da Costa Werlang-198B (esgotaoG) 116. O CICLO ECONÔMICO - Mario Henrique Simonsen - 1988 (esgotado) 117. FOREIGN CAPITAL AND ECONOMIS GROWTH - THE BRAZILIAN CASE ST~JY Mario Henrique Simonsen - 1988 118. cor,mO~J KNOWLEDGE - Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa Wer1ang - 1989(e:ljJtJ.:iJ) 119. OS FUNDAMENTOS DA ANALISE ~ACROECONÔMICA-Prcf.Mario Henrique Simonsen e Prof. Rubens Penha Cysne - 198B (esgotado) 120. CAPíTULO XII - EXPECTATIVASS RACIONAIS - Mario Henrique Simonsen - 1988 (esgotado) 121. A OFERTA AGREGADA E O MERCADO DE TRABALHO - Prof. Mario Henrique Sim o n s e n e P r o f. R u b e n s P e nOh a Cy s n e - 1 9 8 8 (e s 9 o t a do) 122. I1J~RCIA INFLA.CIONARIA E HJFLAÇAO HlE?CIAL- - Prof. Mario He'l:-:.;Üf! Simonen - 1988 (esgot~do) 123. 1'-10DELOS DO rlOf~Eí'l: ECO;iCi':IA E ,ll.o:'lIrnSTRAçÃO - Antonio r:',Jl-ia rLI Silveira - E1ZjB 124. U~Jll[rnrJ\JllICI;JG DF EXPORiS OVERHJVOIC::!:i~C DF n1PQRTS, M:D TW: DlJLLf\R PFt=YIUií O r·) THr= flLP.l,K iJ);J.Ri<ET - ?rof. Fe'!:'n~mdo dc flOl.lí'i~:J [i :::!):;;l, Prof ° f~ut",ói'3 ?e>rikJ Cy:::Jne E: ;';ôrcos Costa Ho12nd3 - 1988 (esgot:-ldo) I 1 7. ~. O R(J NCl r~ A[, J CO OO CH OQli [ H[ 1 ~ F: OD[l XO - F E' r n a ri d O d (;I Hn 1 ~ ri Ó a B~ ;" b [) S;) A11 t o ri j o SLI 1 u Z LI r Pe s S D tJ B r a n ~ u o c C1 (l v i s d e F a r O - 1 9 O8 (~ s 9 11 t iJ d Q ) 1 2 (,. PL Ar~ ú CRUZ fi DCJ: COI; ~, [ p ç ~ O [ Penh~ -127. Cysnp - D E RRO D [ P OL 11 1 CA r I 5 CAL - Ru b (' n s 1988 lAXfJ, DE JUr:,[t~ rLU1Ur,InE VrRSUS C(lRREÇ1~u ~Otnl.4F;JA O'AS PRESTJiÇUES: UI-1A Cor';PAR{,ç.~G r~o CASO DO 5JIC [ JrJFLAÇT\O COf,SlhNT[- Clovis úe furo - 19bG 128. CAPiTULO JJ - t'.[1r~[TAp.y COr.RECTIO!~ - .Rub~n~ P~nh2 Cysnc - 1988 129. CAPiTULO ]~l Pen~~ Cy~n~ - I~COKE Ar~~ 'REAL IN1ERESl ACCOUrnli~:; ANDDEMANO POLICIES 130. CAP11ULO IV - 8RAZ1LIAN ECONOKY IN CRlSIS - Ruber~ PEnha Cysne - 1908 1 31. TP. E fj IN BRAZIL - Rubcn~ - 1988 lHE EIGHTIES AND F: ;; Z1 L Ir~J! AGR1 CUL TUR~. L P OL I CY E XP ERI EIJ CE: fUTURC DIR[CTI01;S - Anionlo Sc:lõzar lHE OEBT RAT I Or~ AL E A1\ D Pessoa Brandão - 1988 132. r·~ OF\ ". i 6r:: J A 1 In ERl~ A, o 1 v I D,'\ PÚB L I C A E J UF. o 5 RE AIS - t'. a r i õ Si 1 v :l Ba5to~ !~t.-rqu~s e SÉrgio Ribeiro dê Costa lJerlõng - 1985 133. CAPlTULO 1>: - TEORIA 00 CRESL:It-',ErJTQ ECOr--;Ôr·~ICD Sirr,ons2n - 1988 2 Mario Henric.;u2 13l; • COI~GELr\l·~EtlTO cm·i p.BOrW SALARIAL GERANDO EXCESSO DE DEr"ÍAr~D;' - JocCiU:lr.l Vieirc. Ferreira Levy e SÉrgio Ribeiro de C.osta IL1erlang - 29:E 135. AS ORIGENS E CONSEqUtNCIAS DA INrLAç~O NA AMERICA LAT!~A Fernando de Holance Barbosa - 1988 136. A CO~TA-CORRENTE DO GOVERNO - 1970-1988 - ~ Mario Henrique 137. A REVIEU ON lHE THEORY DF COMKO~ KNOWLEQGE - S~rgiD Ribeiro da Costa Werlang - 1989 138. ~ACROECG~O~lA - ferncndc de Holanda 82rbosa - 1989 (esgotadu) 139. TEORIP DO EALAr~çO DE PAGAI-~ENTOS: Ur--'A ABORDAGEr., SIMPLIFICADA - João Luiz Tenreiro Barroso - 1989 l~O. CO~TABILIDADE 1~1. "CF:EDIT COM JUROS REAIS - PJ\TIOt~lt~G Af,D THE PERI·:At:[tn Tommy Tan. Daniel Vicent. S~rgio RUBE~S It~CO!':E: PENHA CYSNE - 1989 HYPOTHESIS" - Vicente ~·.adriç:éll, Ribeiro da Costa Wer1ang - 1989 llj2. liA AMAZONIA BRASILEIRA".- Ney Coe· de Oliveira - 1989 143. D~S~GIO DAS LFTs E A PROBABILIDADE IMPLICITA DE MORA1C~IA Maria Silvia Bastos Karques e S~rgio Ribeiro da Costa ~erlanf - lSSS 1~4. THE Loe OEBT PROBLEM: A GAME-THEORETICAL ANALYSIS Mario Henrique Simonsen e Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa Werlang - 1989 n 1~5. ANALISE CONVEXA NO R - Mario Henrique Simonsen - 1989 . 1~6. A CONTROVtRSIA MONETARISTA NO· HEMISrERIO NORTE Fernando de Holanda Barbosa - 1989 147. FISCAL REFORM AND STAB1LIZATION: THE BRAZILI~N EXPERIENCE - Fcrn~ndo de Hol~nda Barbosa, Antônio ~alazar Pessoa Brand~o e Clovis de F~ro - 1989 148. RETOR::OS Er-1 EDCC1\ÇÃO Ca::los Ivan sir!cI1s(?n ~,10 BRASIL: 1976-1986 Leal e Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa \'Jerlang - 1929 149. PREFERE~CES, COMMON K~OWLEDGE, ANO SPECULATIVE TRADE - James Dow, vicente Madrigal, S~rgio Ribeiro da Costa Wer1ang - 1990 150. FDUCAC~O S DIS7RIBUIÇ~O DE RENDA C él r 1 o.s I v a n S ir~ o 11 :3 '2 n - L e a 1 e S é r 9 i o R i b e i r o d a Co s t a - 1990 151. OBSERVAÇ(:JE3 À l'lARGE~~ DO Coe de Oliveira - 1990 T~ABALHO "A M1AZONIA BRASILEIRA" Ney 152. PLAKO COLLOR: UM GOLPE DE MESTRE CONTRA A INFLAÇÃO? - Fernando de Holanda Barbosa - 1990 153. O EFEITO DA T,~XA DE JUROS E DA It\CF:RTEZ'" SOBRE A CURVA DE PHILLl?.'3 DA ECONOMIA ERASIL2IRA - Ricardo de Oliveira Cavalcanti - 1990 154. PLANO COLLOR: CO~7RA FACTUALIDADE E SUGESTOES SOBRE  CONDUÇ~O DA POLíTICA MONeTÁRIA-FISCAL - Rubens Penha CyGne - 1990 155. DEPOSITOS DO TESOURO: ~O BANCO CENTRAL OU NOS BANCOS COMERCI~IS? Rubens Penha Cysne - 1990 156. SISTEMA FINA~CEIRO DE HABITAÇAo: A QUESTÃO DO DESEQUILíBRIO FCVS - Clovis de Faro - 1990 157. COi-1PLE;'lE~JTO DO FAScíCULO N2151 DOS "ENSl\IOS ECONOr-nCOS" ZONIA BRASILEIRA) - Ney Coe de Oliveira - 1990 DO (A Mll\- 158. POLíTICA MCNETÂRIA ÓTIMA NO COMBATE À INFLAÇÃO - Fernando de Holanda Barbosa - 1990 159. TEORIA DOS JOGOS - CONCEITOS BÂSICOS - Mario Henrique Simonscn - 1990 ]60. O MERCADO A8ERTO BRASILEIRO: ANÂLISE DOS PROCEDIMENTOS OPERACIO· ~AIS - Fernando de Holanda Barbosa - 1990 161. A RELAÇ~O ARBITRAGEM ENTRE A ORTN CAMBIAL E A ORTN MONETÂRIA - - Luiz Guilherme Schyl!'ura de Oliveira - 1990 162. SUBADDITIVE PROBABILITIES AND PORTFOLIO INERTIA - Mario Simonsen e S~rgio Ribeiro d0 Costa Werlang - 1990 163. Ilenri~ue ~lJ1CROECO;:0:nA COl'l r-14 - Carlos Ivan Simonsen Leal e S~rgio Ribeiro d,:l C03t.:1 Werlang - lSi90 164. A RF:-EXl.._:íI~~!"TIO;\ O~-' SOLOíi I S GPOí'iTIl r'lODSL HITH l'... PPL lCA'~'IO'l~ C A P I ':';., L r1 O V E :'; r~ l JT S - i:1c?~] n t r o S () él V e d r.'l R i v <" no - 1 990 '1'" .. " PURLIC Cf!Orc:r:: :;;::l1ITH)'J: 'v,"\:-~rr\TIO:~S ml TPE Tflf.l'lE OF' SCTI;~:'n!T" - Antonio Mario 2~ Silvelre - 1990 lGG. TIrE nCI~LIC CHOIeS pr;;PSrr::CTIVE ]\:~D lZf\lIGIIfT1'S If\lS'1.'I'T'{J'T'IO·\ll'LlS'l' !',J:'!'(' - l\ntonio :1.Jr Ll ua Silv(;irêt '- J 0()Ó lG5. 'fi;!; WA~FARS 1G7. 'rIm INDLTi;I:;H::A1'IO:l OI-' Sl':NIOE - Antonio I/li1r ic1 lla silvciri1 -1. ~)')(J • 168. JAPANESE DIRECT INVESTMENT IN BRAZIL - Neantro Saavedra Riva no - 1990 169. A CARTEIRA DE AÇOES DA CORRETORA: UMA ANÁLISE ECONOMICA-Luiz Guilherme Schymura de Oliveira - 1991 170. PLANO COLLOR: OS PRIMEIROS NOVE MESES - Clovis de Faro -1991 171. PERCALÇOS DA INDEXAÇ~O EX-ANTE - Clovis de Faro - 1991 172. NOVE PONTOS SOBRE O PLANO COLLOR 11 - Rubens Penha Cysne-19991 173. A DINÂMICA DA HIPERINFLAÇ~O - Fernando de H. Barbosa, Waldyr Muniz Oliva e E1via Mureb Sa11um - 1991 174. LOCAL CONCAVIFIABILITY OF PREFERENCES AND DETERMINACY OF EQUILIBRIUM - Mario Rui Pascoa e Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa Wer lang - Maio de 1991 000056535 \\ \\l\Il\Il\Il\\lI"I\lI\I"'I\1 1\\1\