Global Trade and Customs Journal Contents Articles 319 A Survey of the EU Tariff Classification Case Law in Year 2010 Davide Rovetta & Patricio Díaz Gavier 325 The Review of the WTO Dispute Settlement Process Marco Tulio Molina Tejeda & Fernando Piérola 339 Customs Audits, Verifications and Voluntary Disclosures in Canada Daniel L. Kiselbach & Dalton Albrecht 343 Trade Remedies: China and the WTO Dispute Settlement Resolution Yanning Yu 351 Investment Regulation and Intellectual Property Katarzyna Jozwik 361 Development and Innovation: The Role of State Enterprises Marcia Carla Pereira Ribeiro & Eduardo Oliveira Agustinho 377 WCO Framework of Standards: Authorized Economic Operator (AEO) in the World Carsten Weerth Interview 381 Nasim Deylami Dj Wolff Column 385 Final Nail in the Zeroing Coffin? Laura Fraedrich Volume 6, Issue 7/8, 2011 ARTICLE Development and Innovation: The Role of State Enterprises Marcia Carla Pereira Ribeiro & Eduardo Oliveira Agustinho* While society is changing at speeds never seen before, some questions arise about the impact that new technology causes and will cause in the lives of citizens. Unfortunately, not all innovation leads to development, and not all development is of a global nature. In this context, the law presents interesting alternatives. The state can play an important role in regional economic development through state enterprises. State enterprises ally with private and public investment, which assures that the interest of the collective prevails. However, the performance of state enterprises is very limited by the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (hereinafter ‘SCM Agreement’). To a certain extent, the restrictions therein contradict the sole aim of the agreement, which clearly expresses the importance of subsidies in economic development. This paper analyzes the legal system of state enterprises within Brazil and their recent successes, as a basis to rethink the limitations imposed by the SCM Agreement. the current social and economic organizations, which caused the financial crisis that spread from North America throughout the global economy. To remedy the flaws of liberalism, the state has had to invest billions to ensure that normality once again runs the market, which has brought the state and the market into a closeness not previously imagined by liberalism. Even the most solid, non-interventionist nations are discussing mixed public-private entrepreneurships. SCEs, which were either established as such or have become public because the state is the major shareholder, offer their structure of private law to the interest of the collectivity, which is considered relevant or essential not only to social well-being but also, most of all, to development. As access to goods and information became global, it became more difficult to accept the exclusion of some or sometimes of many. As was so vividly shown in marketing campaigns, goods and services that were perfected by science and technology came in the thousands, a miracle that, at least on the surface, seemed like a passport to happiness. However, the term ‘development’ carries many connotations; real development depends on state entrepreneurships to widen the access to information and new technology that improves the living conditions of a society. This paper first approaches the definition of state enterprises, which is included in clause 173 of the 1. INTRODUCTION Constant changes in society bring to mind questions about the impact that new technology causes and will cause on the quality of life of citizens. Unfortunately, not all innovation leads to development, and not all development is of a global nature. In this context, the law presents interesting alternatives. The state, through state enterprises and in special statecontrolled enterprises (SCEs), plays an important role in regional development so that citizens can enjoy fairer and more comfortable lives. SCEs integrate private and public investment and emphasize the interests of the collectivity in justifying their creation and profit. This symbiosis of public and private has been reinforced since the 1990s. Developing countries face the need to reformulate their policies of public investment because of the gradual withdrawal of the public agent, which promotes a more decentralized economy. High production costs, scarce public resources, the need to adequately adapt to the rules of the multilateral system of international trade, and the intentional detachment of the state have caused many state enterprises to go private. Monopolies have been replaced by a competitive market economy system. However, there is increasing recognition that we must avoid the excesses of freedom that are typical of Note * For Marcia Carla Pereira Ribeiro: Professor of Commercial Law at Universidade Federal do Paraná (UFPR) and Pontifícia Universidade Católica do Paraná (PUC/PR). Doctor of Law. Attorney. E-mail: [email protected]. Eduardo Oliveira Agustinho: Professor of Commercial Law at Pontifícia Universidade Católica do Paraná (PUC/PR). Master of Law. Attorney. E-mail: [email protected]. 361 Global Trade and Customs Journal, Volume 6, Issue 7/8 © 2011 Kluwer Law International. Development and Innovation: The Role of State Enterprises AQ1 AQ2 Brazilian Constitution, SCEs, state-owned enterprises (SOEs), and third parties. The second part focuses on corporate law by approaching the managerial structure of state enterprises and includes some observations to evaluate the performance of state entrepreneurships using the Copel case study as an example of the Brazilian experience. The third part deals with the limits that are imposed by the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (hereinafter ‘SCM Agreements’), which establishes policies for state enterprises in the pursuit of development, and this contradicts the aim of the document. The final part approaches the meaning of the word ‘development’ according to the economist and Nobel prize winner Amarthya Sen in ‘Development as Freedom’;1 innovation is the basis that is needed to overcome the current financial crisis. Therefore, the importance of SCEs is in this way demonstrated, and the stage is set for the need to reopen the discussion of the restrictions on subsidies in the Multilateral Trading System (MTS). Direct actions are not common because of the principles of free will and private property that are established in the Constitution,6 and therefore, goods and services should be provided mainly by private entities that are organized as companies. The state is in the market through state enterprises and is restricted to the needs of the relevant collective interest and national safety.7 The boundaries for both direct interventions of the state in the economy are, as a matter of fact, in the definition of the legal situations that fit the constitutional presuppositions above, but both have undetermined contents. Therefore, it is not possible to establish, a priori, all cases that are a matter of national safety or of a relevant collective interest, as these pretenses find borderlines in the language. According to the Constitution in clause 173, the law defines the premises mentioned above. Because it is clearly impossible to exhaust hypotheses where a direct intervention of the state would be needed, the Constitution can only establish general criteria to identify these possible situations.8 However, the infra-constitutional legislator is not totally free to define the contents of the above-mentioned concepts.9 To be legitimate and to act in the defense of the relevant interests of the collectivity, the entrepreneurial state must be directly associated with the need to intervene to correct flaws in the market.10 Sporadic international crises, such as the current financial crisis that started in the stock market in North America, are a risk to the economic development of the nation, and thus, a justification to call the state to intervene in the economy based on the relevant interest of the collectivity is required. This current crisis presents a special opportunity for economic and social development, for example, an opportunity to find a more efficient use of natural resources, which is discussed later. Regarding the national safety issue mentioned in the clause 173, even if part of the doctrine gives this clause a wider meaning,11 in general, it has been 2. THE SYMBIOSIS OF PUBLIC AND PRIVATE INTERESTS: CONSTITUTIONAL PATHS AQ3 In a democratic system, the state should provide for the basic rights (as it is understood in clauses 1º, 3º, 5º, 6º, and 170º of the Brazilian Constitution) that act directly in the economy through state enterprises under the regime of a legal monopoly2 or indirectly as a regulating agent3 through mandatory or inductive norms and regulations.4 Indirectly, regulations come as norms through due legal procedures within the Constitution following the principles of administrative law, and they can occur through control (e.g., the state as the police, Conselho Administrativo de Defesa Econômica – CADE), stimuli (e.g., investment banks), and the planning of the state as part of the economy.5 Notes 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Amarthya Sen, Desenvolvimento como liberdade (Development as Freedom), trans. Laura Teixeira Motta (São Paulo: Editora Schwarcz, 2007). Constitution, clause 177. Ibid., clause 173 §§ 1º and 2. João Bosco Leopoldino da. Fonseca, Direito Econômico (Rio de Janeiro: Forense, 2005), 272; Eros Roberto Grau, A ordem econômica na constituição de 1988, 6.ed. rev. e atual (São Paulo: Malheiros, 2001), 163. Constitution, clauses 165 c/c 84, XI; 61, §1º, ‘b’; 63, I; 166, caput and §§3º, 4º, 5º, 6º; 165, §9º; 59, only paragraph; 174. Ibid., clause 170 caput and para. II of the Federal Constitution of 1988. Ibid., clause 173. Marcos Juruena Villela Souto, Direito administrativo da economia (Rio de Janeiro: Lumen Juris, 2003), 86; Lúcia Vale Figueiredo, Curso de direito administrativo, 6.ed. rev. atual. e ampl (São Paulo: Malheiros, 2003), 112. Figueiredo, 112. Eduardo J. Rodríguez Chirillo, Privatizacion de la empresa publica y post privatizacion: analisis juridico (Buenos Aires: Abeledo-Perrot, 1995), 75–76. Álvaro Lazzarini, Temas de direito administrativo, 2.ed. rev. e ampl (São Paulo: Revista dos Tribunais, 2003), 140. Global Trade and Customs Journal, Volume 6, Issue 7/8 © 2011 Kluwer Law International. 362 Marcia Carla Pereira Ribeiro & Eduardo Oliveira Agustinho attributed a stricter meaning, which included the production of weapons to keep the army well-equipped.12 It is important to say that the state is to be in the market in a competitive regime with private companies13 as foreseen in the Constitution.14 Nevertheless, it is evident that there is the possibility that the state might have no competition, for example, in the supply of a certain kind of goods or services that the private sector is not providing. What cannot be admitted is that a state keeps the right to explore to itself and exploits a certain area that hinders the onset of competition in that sector.15 Similarly, the link that is established between the Public Power and the principle of free competition must be examined under three different angles: (1) the state, through legislative mechanisms,16 intervenes to correct competition deviations in the market; (2) the state reaches the same goal through enterprises; and (3) the state respects the principle of free competition in the market. In the first and the second cases, the state acts to assure that constitutional norms are followed, and in the third case, the state follows the Constitution. Consequently, it can be said that the principle of free competition is also presented as a condition for state entrepreneurships, which leads to the impossible condition that what is imperative to national safety and relevant to the interest of the collectivity requires state companies in a regime of monopoly. is ensured, and (5) to follow the private company’s regime. Decree-law 200/67, mainly in clause 5o, III, establishes an SCE as an entity under private law, created by law to be in the market as a limited liability company in which the major shareholder with rights to vote is the union or the state entity that directly administers it.17 Law 6.404/76, LSA, rules that limited liability companies do not have as a concept the definition of SCEs but delineates the basics for the structure and management of companies where the state holds the majority of shares.18 In fact, the law only authorizes these entities to be created19 when, in addition to following private law, SCEs are formed by due constitutional acts.20 The object of an SCE must express a greater need and a general interest that will prevail in the case of a potential conflict between the general interest and the private interest of shareholders (which is consistent with having a profit). 3.1. State-Owned Enterprises Like SCEs, SOEs are entities of indirect public management that, through previous legal authorization, are in the market as established in clause 173 of the Constitution and are subject to the private rights regime, which follows the same rules described previously. However, in this case, only the state or public bodies can be partners. Moreover, they can follow any kind of corporate organization and can even be different from the pre-existing legal models,21 including the detached assets of the state and the company.22 Other political entities and respective indirect management are allowed as long as public rights hold the majority of votes, including a unilateral entrepreneurship when the resources come from only one public entity, a situation that is ordinarily not accepted by the legal Brazilian order.23 Besides SCEs 3. STATE ENTERPRISES As previously mentioned, to perform in the economy, the state can make use of SOEs, SCEs, and third parties according to clause 173, section 1o of the Constitution. SCEs are created when the state wants to join both private and public assets. Legally, however, the following conditions are imperative: (1) previous legal authorization, (2) a main public or collective interest, (3) to be a limited liability company, (4) state control Notes 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 Celso Ribeiro Bastos, Comentários à constituição do Brasil: promulgada em 5 de outubro de 1988 (São Paulo: Saraiva, 1988), v.7, 73; Tadeu Pereira, Regime(s) jurídico(s) das empresas estatais que exploram atividade econômica (Porto Alegre: Síntese, 2001), 53–54. Free competition (clause 170, IV of the FC/88) in a free economy is assured to private entities (clause 170, only paragraph of FC/88). Fábio Konder Comparato, Direito público: estudos e pareceres (São Paulo: Saraiva, 1996), 146; Celso Antônio Bandeira de Mello, Curso de direito administrativo, 16.ed. rev. atual. e ampliada (São Paulo: Malheiros, 2003), 639. It is also possible to have a state monopoly instated by law (Grau, 308). Law 8.884/94, Antitrust Law. Clause 37, XIX – Constitution. Maria Sylvia Zanella Di Pietro, Direito administrativo, 16.ed. (São Paulo: Atlas, 2003), 387. Ibid., at 370. Constitution, Arts 45 and 985 of the New Civil Code. Sérgio Andrea Ferreira, ‘O direito administrativo das empresas governamentais brasileiras’, Revista de Direito Administrativo, Rio de Janeiro, n. 136, 1–33, Abr./Jun. 1979, 51. Alvaro A. Caminha Muniz, A empresa pública no direito brasileiro (Rio de Janeiro: Edições Trabalhistas, 1972), 51. Clause 251 of LSA regulates the ‘whole subsidiary’, a singular hypothesis of unilateral personality. 363 Global Trade and Customs Journal, Volume 6, Issue 7/8 © 2011 Kluwer Law International. Development and Innovation: The Role of State Enterprises and SOEs, the state can also control using concessionbased systems.24 are also delegated to private companies in a regime of competition, the state must relinquish the inherent prerogatives and, by being in the same position of private agents in the sector, subject itself to ‘the legal regime of private agents, even when it comes to rights, civil duties and commercial, labour and tax commitments’.28 Although the above-mentioned sends us back to the elaboration of a legal statute, the submission of state companies that are in the market to the norms of private law is needed and immediate because it is not being conditioned by any legislation to come.29 Taking into consideration that the state should be admitted in this sector only exceptionally and in a competitive regime with the private sector, it is valid to assume that the Constitution only states the aim of the constitutional order and withdraws from the legislator any possibility to state in an ordinary law the benefits or advantages that set the state entrepreneur in a privileged situation. Therefore, the link to the private legal regime is concerned with the minimum content to be foreseen in the legal statutes of state enterprises and cannot be created exactly from its writing. In the public and private sectors, the scope of the protection of private entities against unfair competition would broaden if the state could use its prerogatives and immunity as a corporation. Moreover, the private system is generally the main reason for the existence of SCEs, SOEs, and concessions. The state chooses entrepreneurships to have a freer public sector with the agility and flexibility that is inherent to good performance in the market.30 However, it has to be considered that the link between state enterprises and the private regime does not make them equal to corporations31 because of the constitutional regime, that is, in the applicability of the public administration principles, as there is a link between the entity and the political agent that created and controls it. In other words, because of public investment, the state enterprises that are in the market should settle on the principles of corporate law that rule the matter in general but also fit the specific norms of administrative law. 3.2. State Enterprises that Provide Public Services: Submission to Clause 173 The previous considerations lead to the conclusion that if the presupposed interest of the collectivity and national safety are present under a market economy system, the state will be allowed to develop entrepreneurships that are typical of the private sector. Consequently, the state enterprises that provide the public services stated in the Constitution are not to be included, a priori, in these dispositions directly or through concessions, which make the aforementioned constitutional ruling inapplicable.25 What remains, however, is only the applicability of the public rights norms, which does not fit in with the discussion of a legal statute that establishes its submission to the legal regime of private companies. However, we must not lose sight of the fact that the Brazilian state has chosen to delegate the public services to the private sector, which brings in a new element, competition,26 and demonstrates a tendency that has been seen in other countries, a service of general economic interest.27 This evident change in paradigm leads to a careful consideration of the applicability of the general legal statute to the state enterprises that provide public services that have been delegated to private companies, which, in addition to SOEs, SCEs, and concessions, should submit to the norms stated in the clause 173, section 1º of the Constitution. In addition to ensuring that state enterprises have the needed flexibility to compete with private companies, adherence to Constitutional norms is the only way to assure fair competition. 3.3. Results, Responsibility, and Control in a State-Controlled Enterprise Positioned in the market as an agent that performs the typical role of the private sector (in economic endeavours only) or provides public services that Notes 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 José Edwaldo Tavares Borba, Direito Societário, 8ª ed. (Rio de Janeiro: Renovar, 2003), 497. Grau, 135–140. Carlos Ari Sundfeld & Oscar VilhenaVeira (Coords.), Direito global (São Paulo: Max Limonad, 1999), 161. Vital Moreira, ‘Os serviços públicos tradicionais sob o impacto da União Européia’, Revista de Direito Público da Economia, Belo Horizonte, ano 1, n. 1, 227–228, Abr./Jun. 2003, 239–241. Constitution, clause173, §1º, II. The legal statute cannot give state enterprises ‘tax privileges that do not extend’ to the private companies (clause 173, §2o). Borba, 500. Di Pietro, 385. Celso Antônio Bandeira de Mello, ‘Sociedades de economia mista, empresas públicas e o regime de direito público’, Revista Diálogo Jurídico, Salvador, n. 13. abr./maio 2002, <www.direitopublico.com.br>, viewed on 13 maio 2004. Global Trade and Customs Journal, Volume 6, Issue 7/8 © 2011 Kluwer Law International. 364 Marcia Carla Pereira Ribeiro & Eduardo Oliveira Agustinho Paragraph IV of section 1º of clause 173 refers to private partners of the board in management, and it refers specifically to state enterprises that split the control with other public and private investors. Because this paper aims to set forth new concepts in the context of SCEs, the approach will now be directed to this kind of entrepreneurship. A system that assures absolute power to the controlling shareholder does not, in principle, attract private investment. Therefore, the structure and the political decision to have more or less control will be reflected in effective private investment. Moreover, society is already at a level of organization that does not expect illicit benefits or advantages by the joining of state organizations and its natural power. In countries with a traditional interventionist policy like Brazil, the trust and assurance of the simple participation of the state and the presupposed unconditional solvency should be added to the interest of the common investor. 3.4. State-Controlled Enterprises: Control and Management In the SCE, private shareholders are associated to a state that holds the majority of the company shares and, therefore, control. A controlling shareholder, as defined in clause 116 of the Brazilian limited liability company law (LSA), is the main shareholder with the power to elect the majority of the board and to lead the company due to the effective power. A controlling shareholder has the duty to maximize the interests of the corporation, the shareholders, the workers, and the local community. According to clause 238 of LSA, this controlling shareholder shall lead the company and make decisions to favour the public interest that is directly linked to its own existence. There is an evident contradiction between the two positions above: one of a general nature that establishes the duties of the controlling shareholder according to different interests and another that is centralized in the management of the relevant public interest or national safety that defines the nature of the organization. This limited orientation for the controlling shareholder to run a company is suggested by law and is expressed in the decision-making of the controlling shareholder and managers that necessarily will take into consideration political matters and the macro-economy, which could go against the interest of a minority of shareholders. In addition to direct power and control, the flow of business in a company surfaces when nominees are called to be a part of the board of directors. The development of an entrepreneurship is directly related to investment policies. If private investment is to be privileged, the company must be led to favour the investment that will not occur unless there is a forecasted profit that is associated to the public investment, which is not necessarily directed to profit but is relevant to the interest of the collectivity or a matter of national safety that justifies the state enterprise. 3.5. The Political Condition: Minor and Major Representation in the Board The administrative structure presented by law can be either with one (diretoria) or two boards (diretoria and conselho de administração). In the second, two boards are to lead the company. The diretoria includes shareholders and non-shareholders with technical backgrounds, and conselho de administração, just shareholders. The law demands that SOEs and SCEs are necessarily formed by two boards to assure the state representative in charge in the case of SCEs even with private shareholders that state interest can prevail. This structure obviously has the merit of trying to conciliate professional management through the allocation of specialized staff with the interests of shareholders that are represented in the elected administrative councilors. Officers (called directors) are to be elected in a general assembly or by the administrative council, if there is one, and will consist of at least two people. In the administrative council, which is composed of at least three people who are elected in a general assembly, there can also be a shareholders’ representative, which assures the condition that the controlling shareholder has more representatives.32 In state enterprises, the mandatory representation of workers remains.33 In state enterprises, management is usually nominated by the Executive Office, and shareholders agreements, which organize the division of control in the company, have been questioned in court34 once the control of the state enterprise has been necessarily preserved in the hands of a public entity. In the Notes 32 33 34 Clause 141, §4º of LSA. Law 12.353/10. Brasília, Superior Tribunal de Justiça, Complaint 3016, Dominó Holdings S/A x Estado do Paraná, Redator: Min. Eliana Calmon. Brasília, 21 Oct. 2008. Available at <www.stj.pr.gov.br>, viewed on 24 Oct. 2000. Also Minas Gerais, Tribunal de Justiça do Estado de Minas Gerais, Civil Appeal 000.199.781-6/00, Southern Electric Brasil Participações x Estado de Minas Gerais. Redator: Des. Garcia Leão. Belo Horizonte, 07 Aug. 2001. Available at <www.tj.mg.gov.br>, viewed on 21 Oct. 2008. 365 Global Trade and Customs Journal, Volume 6, Issue 7/8 © 2011 Kluwer Law International. AQ4 Development and Innovation: The Role of State Enterprises administrative structure of state enterprises, especially in an SCE, the representation of different interests that coexist takes on a special connotation. Primarily because the criteria to create the boards are sometimes far from the theory, neither officers nor the administrative council are required to have the needed expertise to represent shareholders. Therefore, the controlling shareholder is the state and the interest of the state is close to the political nature of the groups in power, which makes it difficult to evaluate the different interests that coexist in the organization. For example, in a state enterprise, management positions are given to political parties or benefited parties because of the financial profit the position grants. Evidently, the expert management of a state enterprise is an important element to gather private investment. There are systems that work differently, legally speaking, within an SCE. In France, for example, up to eighteen places are given to shareholders who represent the local community. The same number of places is granted to private shareholders.35 French law allows representatives who are elected by the community to be a part of the management independently of assembly elections and, consequently, independent of their mandate. Would a prevision law be a challenge to the general corporate principles that assure the election of management whether by votes of an assembly or by the deliberation of a council? It is understood that the answer is no; once corporate law allows, for example, the establishment of norms to indicate managers based on agreements, the assembly nominations become a mere formality. Brazilian law requires that the administrative councilor should be a shareholder, but this order can be mediated with the temporary attribution of shares to the person chosen to be in the office. In addition, the principles of corporate management show the convenience of the nomination of a certain number of independent councilors, who are independent from the groups of interest that are created within the corporation, with no need to be a partner or the free choice of an assembly. Therefore, board positions, especially chairs in the council, are dissociated from the traditional democratic model of the free choice of an assembly, which allows for the coexistence of different interests and different sources of power in the centre of the corporation. This reality demands caution in the establishing of rules for the occupation of the management positions in a company and must be based on existing interests. A conflict must not contradict the greater premises that are allocated in a corporation, such as the responsibility of fulfi lling the interests of the company, shareholders, workers, and the community in which it is inserted. If the workers and the community have interests, which are not to be neglected, and are linked to the entrepreneurship that is organized as a corporation, its representation will be more effective through the assurance of the right to vote and elect representatives. In an SCE, there are public interests in addition to the interests of shareholders, investors, workers, and the community. How the management of an SCE bears these interests in mind is a matter to be faced by a special law that rules on state enterprises. The assurance of different representation can change the administrative profi le because of the effective attention given to private shareholders and minorities and the general interests that motivated the partnership. However, the management of the company should stick to the nomination of strictly technical staff using any criteria. Regarding competitive state enterprises in the market, this is not only a matter of survival but also a stimulus for private investment. Political influence and the assurance of harmony in leading the entrepreneurship in a macro-economy should be limited to the indication of chairs in the administrative council (i.e., the board’s first (supervisory) tier) and to the management plan to be followed, which is always a direct duty of the controlling shareholder, in this case, the state that is directly linked to the market in question. In France, the local authority can veto businesses that can compromise the public budget.36 This prerogative is seen as a way to ensure the balance between the interests to dispose of more public assets and what the company can invest. However, private shareholders can use the veto power, which is established in the company’s statutes, to determine certain matters.37 This confrontation of veto powers can aid the desired balance in the management of an SCE without giving up the right to nominate executive positions, which allows the company to be managed by experts. An adequate number of chairs in the administrative council, in addition to the veto power that is given in specific matters that can reasonably coexist with the freedom of managers, can help the search for the ideal management model of a state enterprise. Notes 35 36 37 Corinne Regnaut-Moutier, ‘L’administration de la SEM: propos de privatiste’, in Regards croisé sur l’économie mixte, Guérard, Stéphane, coord. (Paris: L’Harmattan, 2006), 290. André Delion, Le droit des entreprises et participations publiques (Paris: LGDJ, 2003), 227. Regnaut-Moutier, 294. Global Trade and Customs Journal, Volume 6, Issue 7/8 © 2011 Kluwer Law International. 366 Marcia Carla Pereira Ribeiro & Eduardo Oliveira Agustinho the constitutional clause that foresees its inclusion in the legal statute of SOCs and SCEs. Therefore, taking into consideration that legal norms are to be interpreted so that the maximum effectiveness can be extracted from them,40 it is understood that the social role in clause 173, section 1, I of the Constitution reports a duty that is conceived to be imposed on corporations and state enterprises.41 However, this should not be misunderstood with the wider public interest that justifies the existence of the state enterprise. Consequently, it is not enough for the state entrepreneur to pursue the relevant collective interest or the needed national security that gave it the authority to intervene directly in the economy. Like private entrepreneurships, state enterprises must fulfi l the immediate interests of the employees, private shareholders, suppliers, consumers, and the community in general, and it is up to the legal statute to draw the lines for these interests.42 3.6. Evaluating Performance Due to the specific role attributed to an SCE, there is a close link with the SOE, governmental investments, and the financing of the entrepreneurship. There are situations when the public capital increases because of an increase in capital and the subsidy of a future increase, the selling of shares and similar options, financial restructuring programs, and the financial compensations due to measures taken to preserve the public interest. All differentiated increases of public resources, which will unavoidably influence the balance of the company and the profit of the period, will demand specific control to ensure the transparency between the partnership and public resources and assure that disciplinary measures are followed to ensure the workers’ participation in the company profit. This policy prevents distortions in the profit of the period (extraordinary increases of capital to finance re-organization due to compensations for decisions based in the public interest must be due in special accounts). The legal statute of SCEs38 must necessarily have criteria to measure non-financial results that are valued according to the collective interest that motivated the existence of the company, even through quantifiable indexes that would be a parameter for the evaluation of published reports.39 Clause 173, section 1o of the Constitution determines the need of a legal statute on the social role of a state enterprise. However, is accomplishing a social role, either as a national security matter or as a matter that is relevant to the collective interest, the reason that the state is an entrepreneur? The legal literature is not clear when it comes to this matter. However, to think that the state enterprise was created to fulfi l a goal is enough to make viable the principle that the social role would be the same as to reduce to useless 3.7. The Copel Case An example of the strength of the partnership of public and private investment, which promotes development, is the Copel case. In Brazil, the electric energy power sector was developed by private and foreign companies. At first, the cities made concessions. Fragmented, the system was a problem to the sector. It changed in 1934 when the Waters National Code put control under the wing of the Federal State.43 In the 1950s, ‘the electric power was the pillar of the national industrialization process’44 and was considered basic to development45 when the gathering of investments was also basic. Companies were shown to be the most adequate way to gather substantial investment, and in Parana, in 1948, the first state Notes 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 Constitution, clause 173. Delion, 229. José Joaquim Gomes Canotilho Canotilho, Direito constitucional e teoria da constituição, 5.ed. (Coimbra: Livraria Almedina, 2002), 1.208. To Eros Grau, social role is an active command that imposes to the controller of a company the duty to direct the business deals ‘in the benefit of others and not to over-perform in detriment of others’ (supra, 269). It is odd that state enterprises favor the interest of the collective afar from the accomplishment of duties that are the sole reason for its existence. Besides private companies, many state companies develop projects that are inserted in what is known today as ‘social responsibility’. As examples, we have (1) Project ‘Luz das Letras’, developed by Copel – Cia. Paranaense de Energia Elétrica, concentrating on ‘litteracy of the young and adults’; (2) Project Sorrir, implemented by Sanepar – Cia. de Saneamento do Paraná, a ‘tripod of Education, Citizenship and the Hygiene of the Mouth’ for ‘children ages 6 to 14 in the low-income community’ (Pedro Washington de Almeida & Eduardo Almeida, 1.o Anuário de responsabilidade social – Paraná: solutions for the future (Curitiba: Paranapress, 2003), 68–69 e 102– 103). Clause 150. BRASIL. Decree 24.643, 10 Jul. 1934. Decreta o Código de Águas, <www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/decreto/D24643.htm>, viewed on 20 Mar. 2009. História Da Copel, <www.Copel.com>, viewed on 20 Mar. 2009. A Evolução Do Planejamento No Governo Federal. Marcos do Planejamento Público no Brasil 1947 a 2000, <www.planejamento.gov.br/ arquivos_down/spi/publicacoes/evolucao_1.pdf>, viewed on 20 Mar. 2009. 367 Global Trade and Customs Journal, Volume 6, Issue 7/8 © 2011 Kluwer Law International. Development and Innovation: The Role of State Enterprises electric power generation plan46 joined an important binary of economic development: assets and electric power. For the state, the company came as a product and as a tool to facilitate the economy. The rules foreseen for Copel as object are only found in paragraph of clause 9º, which now reads as follows: great deal of service was provided to rural areas and to low-income families. Segredo Power Station was also built, and the Salto Caxias Power Station opened in 1999. Because it needed resources, in 1994, Copel went public by selling shares in the stock market. The goal was to reach the international market, which actually happened in 1998. Going public meant a leap for investment and results and, at the time, was interpreted as a kind of privatization. The open capital structure of the SCE corresponded to the need for voluptuous resources to finance further electric power transmission, gas distribution, and power generation. In 1993, the stock market was favourable, especially to the electric power sector due to fees established for the public service, the extinction of the assured-remuneration regime, and the restructuring of the electric power sector.48 After Copel went public because of the need for investments in maintaining the required service, especially electric power to support economic growth, State Law 10.702, 30 December 1993,49 was written to authorize the government to sell a major part of its shares. The law established that the resources gathered were to be invested in the following manner: (1) 10% in popular houses; (2) 25% in local railways; and (3) 65% in Copel for power generation systems, transmission, and distribution of power. The law established the flow of sales. The re-investment in Copel was an important factor in the rising of share prices. In the late 1990s, the company was in the North American stock market, and it is currently in the European stock market. In 2001,50 after attempts in the United States, there was an unsuccessful privatization, a process made not because of deficit but by the federal government’s choice. Recently, to allow the company to keep the state enterprise status, the law was revoked.51 Copel, as a state enterprise, must necessarily invest in research and development and efficient electric power in the percentages that were established in Law 9.991, 24 July 2000, and regulated by Decree 3.867, 16 July 2001. According to clause 2º, caput, the authorized The company, according to the present clause, itself or through services granted to third parties it is a shareholder, or through a company it will be a shareholder, provided Public Power holds the majority of shares, can: (a) research and study, technical and economic angles of any source of energy; (b) research, study, plan, build and explore production, transformation, transportation, storage, distribution and commerce of any kind of energy, in special electric power, petrol and raw energy sources; (c) study, plan, project, build and operate dams and reservoirs, and other entrepreneurships that have the multiple use of water; (d) provide information service and technical assistance to the rational use of energy to private companies that are to implement and develop activities relevant to the development of the State; (e) perform in electronic information transmission, communication and electronic control, cellular phones, and other activities of interest to Copel and to the state of Parana, being it authorized for these purposes and the ones on items ‘b’ and ‘c’, to participate, as a major shareholder, in leasing or in private companies.47 The company built power stations that minimized the need to import electric power. In the 1960s, it provided energy to the pioneers in the North and the South and, in the 1970s, to the West and the East. In 1980, Foz do Areia Power Station opened, and a Notes 46 47 48 49 50 51 A História Da Energia No Paraná, available at <www.Copel.com>, viewed on 20 Mar. 2009. Paraná. Law 1.384, 10 Nov. 1953. Institui o Fundo de Eletrificação e dá outras providências. Diário Oficial [do Estado do Paraná], Curitiba, Paraná, n. 199, 11 Nov. 1953. 1. Copel [Diretoria] Curitiba. Minutes of the meeting of 08 Nov. 1993. Paraná. Law 10.702, of 30 Dec. 1993. Specific authorization to sell shares. Diário Oficial [do Estado do Paraná], Curitiba, Paraná, n. 4.171, 31 Dec. 1993, 3 and 4. Paraná. Law 12.355, 12/08/1998 Authorizes the Executive Office to re-structure shares, negotiating shares the state has, as well as to get credit, finance, or other negotiations on its own or through Paraná Investimentos S/A and other measures. Diário Oficial [do Estado do Paraná], Curitiba, 12/09/1998, <http://celepar7cta.pr.gov.br/SEEG/sumulas.nsf/319b106715f69a4b03256efc00601826/e74a14 ee0c8520b203256e99006892b1?OpenDocument>, viewed on 20 Mar 2009. Paraná. Law 14.608, 01/10/2005. Revokes law 12.355, of 12/08/1998, that authorized the Executive Office to re-structure Copel shares. Diário Oficial [do Estado do Paraná], Curitiba, 01/28, <http://celepar7cta.pr.gov.br/SEEG/sumulas.nsf/319b106715f69a4b03256efc00601 826/392478666bf 9543783256f9d0060828a?OpenDocument>, viewed on 20 Mar. 2009. Global Trade and Customs Journal, Volume 6, Issue 7/8 © 2011 Kluwer Law International. 368 Marcia Carla Pereira Ribeiro & Eduardo Oliveira Agustinho companies must apply, every year, the minimum amount of 1% of revenues in research and development of the electric power sector, excluding, because of exemption, companies that generate energy exclusively from wind, solar, biomass, small hydroelectric power plants and qualified co-generation. Clause 4º of the same law foresees that: must be national and recognized by the Ministry of Science and Technology – MCT; IV – the high-end teaching institutions must be registered with the Ministry of Education – MEC. The above-mentioned statutes show the clear sustainable nature of the investment in research and development of the electric power sector, with the exemption seen as a stimulus to the use of ‘clean energy’ and to the association of companies and teaching institutions for the development of new technologies. Social responsibility is currently considered basic, nationally and worldwide, and instates the consciousness that companies cannot be limited to commerce, industry, or services. In this context, Copel has been developing some innovating projects. One project, which was presented in September 2008, is a car that runs on electric energy at a speed of 110 km/h and reaches 110 km/h in 28 seconds, a project that was coordinated by Itaipu Binacional. In 2006, a deal was closed with the Swiss Power Station KWO and Lactec – Instituto de Tecnologia para o Desenvolvimento. Eletrobrás and other Brazilian companies in the sector are also investing. The goal is to reach INR 1.4 million. Another project is the Power Line Communication (PLC), which uses the electric power network to access the Internet in 10 megabits extra-broadband and52 is currently being tested in Santo Antonio da Platina, north of Parana. There is also the VoIP system, which is about 76% cheaper than conventional landlines and mobile phones in the state of Parana. If the providers migrate to the optic fibre network that Copel has already installed, the savings are expected to amount to INR 86 million per year, and it will be available to the teaching institutes in the state of Parana. resources are to follow: I – 40% to Fundo Nacional de Desenvolvimento Científico e Tecnológico – FNDCT, created by the decree-law 719, in July 31, 1969, reestablished by the law 8.172, in January 18, 1991; (Writing follows law 10.848, 2004); II – 40% for research and development projects, according to the regulation established by Agência Nacional de Energia Elétrica - ANEEL; (Writing follows law 10.848, 2004); III – 20% to MME, a subsidy for studies and research on planning the expansion of the power system, inventory and viable use of hydroelectric power (law 10.848, 2004). Regarding resources, in paragraph I of clause 4º in Law 9.991/2000, Decree 3.687/2001 says in clause 1º that they will be deposited in FNDCT ‘in a specific category called CT-ENERG, to be used in the research and technological development of the sector and in projects of efficient use of power by the end user’. In the only paragraph of the same document, it says: As to the herein, it is understood as scientific research and technological development: I – projects of scientific and technological research; II – experimental technical development; III – development of the basic technology; IV – infrastructure for research; V – training; VI – diffusion of scientific and technological knowledge. As to the use of resources, it says in clause 5º of Law 9.991/2000 that: I – investment in efficient use of power foreseen in clause 1º, will be according to regulations established by ANEEL; II – a minimum of 30% is to projects developed by research institutions in the North, Northeast and Centre-West of the country and where the respective regional superintendence is; II – at least 30% of the resources in paragraphs I, II and III in clause 4 of this law will be to projects developed by research institutions in the North, Northeast and Centre-West of the country, including where the regional superintendence is; (writing given by law 10.848 of 2004); III – research and development institutes that receive resources 4. SCES, DEVELOPMENT, AND THE SCM AGREEMENT Despite the above facts, which show a positive example of state participation in the economy through state enterprises, it is important to note that this path is currently quite restricted. This restriction is due to economic and legal reasons. The first restriction is the result of the obvious lack of resources, which is present in all developing countries without exception. The second restriction, however, is the consequence of the limits to be observed by these countries, Note 52 Marco Martins, Copel testa internet ‘elétrica’ no Norte Pioneiro. Gazeta do Povo, Tecnologia, 23 Feb. 2009, <portal.rpc.com.br/gazetadop ovo/tecnologia/conteudo.phtml ?tl=1&id=860583&tit=Copel-testa-internet-eletrica-no-Norte-Pioneiro>, viewed on 10 Mar. 2009. 369 Global Trade and Customs Journal, Volume 6, Issue 7/8 © 2011 Kluwer Law International. AQ5 Development and Innovation: The Role of State Enterprises regarding how to behave as an economic agent due to the restrictions imposed by the MTS. Therefore, SCM must be the focus of attention. This agreement is part of the MTS, which is managed by the World Trade Organization (WTO).53 According to this system, a subsidy is usually seen as an undeserved benefit that can generate distortions in competitions in the free international market.54 The use of subsidies, however, is not understood absolutely as something negative. In fact, the goal of the agreement is ‘to strengthen and improve GATT disciplines related to the use of SCM, while, at the same time, recognizing the right of members to use such measures under certain conditions’.55 Therefore, the importance of state intervention in the economy through subsidies as a tool to reach development is recognized. What is searched, on that account, is the conciliation of these two antagonistic points of view on subsidies, either as a factor of distortion in international trade or as a valid tool to promote economic development. Through the SCM Agreement, the legal concept of subsidy is established. For a certain measure to be characterized as subsidy, there must be (1) a financial contribution by the government or any public body, (2) a benefit, and (3) specificity. The last requirement establishes the need of the state subvention to be submitted to specific access, de jure or de facto, (1) to an enterprise or industry, (2) to a group of enterprises or industries, or (3) to certain enterprises located within a designated geographical region. With these criteria being established, the subsidies are divided into two kinds: prohibited and actionable. Among the prohibited subsidies are any measures that link financial contributions from the government to export performance conditions or to the use of domestic over imported goods. Aside from the above, subsidies can be considered actionable if they generate adverse effects to international trade when (1) subsidies may lead to displacement of imports in the subsiding country, (2) subsidized products may displace otherwise competitive domestic products in the importing country, or (3) subsidies may cause displacement of otherwise competitive exports from third countries. The SCM Agreement still foresaw, during a transition period that ended in 31 December 1999, a list of non-actionable subsidies that involved financial contributions from the government under certain conditions to (1) assist research, (2) assist a general framework of regional development, or (3) promote the adaptation of existing facilities to new environmental requirements. However, it also established that in a transition period that ended in 2003, developing countries could have subsidies in export, which is now prohibited under the Agreement. Currently, this special treatment is only applied to least developed countries and developing countries with less than GDP 1,000 per capita. With the strict exception of the least developed countries, the same legal regime is applied indistinctly to all WTO members, which severely limits the use of subsidies in developing countries. Therefore, it has become evident that there is a certain imbalance in the closeness of subsidies as displacement factors in international trade and as valid tools for the promotion of economic development, which promotes concerns, in the case of the WTO, about the preservation of the first factor. This imbalance, in turn, affects how state enterprises might perform among the different kinds of financial contributions, which are exemplified in the SCM Agreement as subsidies, that is, to increase the working capital in a company. This does not mean that the state cannot be an entrepreneur through SOCs and SCEs, but the investments that are made must be compatible with common market procedures. Actually, in the MTS, there is no concern with the public or private nature of the partners in an enterprise. In short, it is understood that the World Trade System has an ownership-neutral position. Some reasons for this attitude can be perceived. At first, it is a question of a ‘position legally consistent with the requirements of international law’, which preserves state autonomy in the definition of its social, political, and economic systems. In addition, after the Great Depression in the 1930s, developing countries ‘also established SOEs as tools for achieving objectives of government policies’.56 With that being said, that the possibility of state interference in the economy through state enterprises is, until today, compatible with international trade can be noted. However, the allowance of subsidies to these corporations as a means of implementing public policies is strictly forbidden. In the context of the current legal Brazilian setting, the possibility of an SCE to benefit through subsidies due to an increase in capital is very unlikely. The certainty of this statement is based in two elements of the current legislation. First, it is important to note that SCEs, as seen above and as Notes 53 54 55 56 Rabih Ali Nasser, A OMC e os países em desenvolvimento (São Paulo: Aduaneiras, 2002), 133–232. Mitsuo Matsushita, Thomas Schoenbaum & Petros C. Mavroidis, The World Trade Organization: Law, Practice and Policy (New York: Oxford University Press, 2003), 260. Appellate Body Report, United States – Final Countervailing Duty Determination with respect to Certain Softwood Lumber from Canada (hereinafter ‘US – Lumber CVD Final’), WT/DS257/AB/R, adopted 17 Feb. 2004, para. 64. Julia Ya Qin, ‘WTO Regulation of Subsidies to State-Owned Enterprises (SOEs) – A Critical Appraisal of the China’, Journal of International Economic Law 7 no. 4 (2004): 899–900. Global Trade and Customs Journal, Volume 6, Issue 7/8 © 2011 Kluwer Law International. 370 Marcia Carla Pereira Ribeiro & Eduardo Oliveira Agustinho constitutionally determined,57 develop an activity in competition and under the same legal regime as corporations, which are inadequate at adopting any kind of privileged treatment that is restricted only to state enterprises. In addition, these enterprises have their share capital that is composed of private resources as well. Therefore, the utter economic logic of the market disposes of the hypothesis that their management is not concerned with future revenues because, even if the state is not worried about collecting dividends, the same cannot be said about the other partners. In short, the balance that comes from the conflict of interests between the state and private partners adds to the fact that this kind of state enterprise is not benefited by subsidies as a means to increase capital. The same cannot be said about SOEs because the investment is solely from the state in this case. Subsidies in this sphere are one of the most complex possibilities of improper incentives. However, it is a plausible situation in some economic sectors for infrastructure. In this case, if a state enterprise develops its end activity in a situation where the working costs are higher than the expected future results, this is a situation that can be understood as subsidy because the state, by taking over the financial losses, makes a contribution that benefits this company, which makes it more competitive in international trade. Despite this fact, there is no rule in MTS forbidding its use in SOEs. What we have is an incentive measure for developing countries to privatize these enterprises.58 Based on this premise, Brazil launched a National Program in the 1990s to end public ownership when several state enterprises went private. However, the possibility of state participation in these corporations with the veto power remained in an attempt to protect the interest of the collectivity that, at some point, justified them.59 A renowned example of this process is Embraer S/A, the Brazilian aircraft manufacturer that was made private and became known in the international trade of aircrafts when it became involved in a disputed competition with the Canadian Bombardier. In this case, the dispute ended in a panel in the WTO in which the program installed in Brazil to equalize the credit offer in the international stock exchange market companies in developed countries had to be equal to the credit offered to Brazilian companies. The program was considered a specific benefit and, therefore, inappropriate.60 The case above shows two pertinent considerations to the subject of state enterprises and their performance. First, the possibility of a Brazilian company participating in a high-end market, such as aviation, in equal competitive conditions with companies from developed countries is, no doubt, the result of the state having allowed this enterprise to exist. In addition, the showing of the need of financial equalization measures to allow a higher competitive level in these markets shows that there still is a lack of equality between developed countries and developing countries in the international context that justifies different agreements in subsidy policies. Therefore, the transition period in the SCM Agreement must be reviewed to even up the balance in the World Trade System. As one observer of the challenges of Chinese access to MTS, ‘Chinese SOEs have helped to demonstrate the necessity of rethinking the role of subsidies and WTO subsidy rules in general … For example, should WTO subsidy disciplines regulate different types of subsidies according to their purposes as well as their trade effects?’.61 5. SOES:TOOLS FOR ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL DEVELOPMENT The lack of balance in the definition of subsidies limits can be understood as a consequence of the fact that it is marked by elements that originate from a neoclassical understanding of development. Therefore, a possible path to rethinking the system can come from re-reading these premises. The never-ending search for industrialization and economic development has led most countries around the world to concentrate efforts in the promotion of growth of the GDP, which relegated quality of life to a second level. Economic growth is seen as the means and end of development. In ‘Development for Freedom’, Amarthya Sen sets forth the difficulty of not only understanding development but also limiting the concept of evaluating the growth of a country through relative criterion such as income growth (i.e., the population purchasing power). This economist evaluates development differently, especially the substantive freedom that includes, for example, political freedom, economic facilities, Notes 57 58 59 60 61 Constitution, clause 173, §1º, II. SCM Agreement, Art. 27.14. LSA, Art. 17, §7º. Appellate Body Report, Brazil – Export Financing Program for Aircraft, Report of Panel, WT/DS46/R, adopted 14 Apr. 1999, para. 8.1. Qin, 919. 371 Global Trade and Customs Journal, Volume 6, Issue 7/8 © 2011 Kluwer Law International. Development and Innovation: The Role of State Enterprises social opportunities, transparency, and the protective safety. When freedom is expanded, the main means of development consists of the removal of many kinds of restrictions that leave people with few, if any, choices and opportunities. Certain kinds of freedom have an instrumental role in the promotion of freedoms of other natures, such as education and health, which complement individual opportunities to participate in economic and political endeavours in addition to being a stimulus to overcome poverty. Due to the issues discussed above, an approach based on the identification of freedom as the main object of development according to the principles of Sen will follow. conditions to live a life that is viable and chosen, if needed, through the aid of public policies or by having an influence in these policies, which fall under political freedom. Therefore, if there is freedom and the individuals are ready to earn their living through work, it is crucial that the economic condition in the country gives them access to work. Otherwise, the decision to work lacks effectiveness. This is where the access to knowledge and technology is pertinent. Consequently, if development is associated with a level of freedom in addition to the psychological aspect and if this freedom is viable, the more generalized the access to information, the bigger the perspective of development. 5.1. Political Freedom 5.3. Destitution of Freedom According to Sen, ‘in general, we have excellent reasons to want more income or wealth, though not because we want them for their own sake, but because they are the means to have more freedom to live the kind of life we have reasons to value, as wealth is the means to reach the desired life’.62 It is undeniable that economic development plays an important role to this end; however, growth is not the end itself. Development linked to economic growth does not lead automatically to a decrease in social discrepancies because the growth alone with no concern of the distribution can worsen the lack of equality. Development, in addition to economics, can be valued by the oportunity given to an individual to exert freedom. As a matter of fact, development presupposes, on the one hand, a better organization of the market and, on the other, the implementation of public policies that, according to Sen, are not enough to ensure a lasting improvement in living conditions. Stable markets, according to studies, are efficient tools for growth. Still, when the question is analysed under the prism of freedom, especially political freedom, according to Sen, there are few signs that authoritarian politicies aid social improvement because, in theory, democratic regimes that reach for votes induce governors to avoid social comotions, especially when they come with hunger.63 Sen shows that there is no freedom when there are no opportunities and when hunger and malnutrition are the reasons that part of the society does not have full access to the basic freedom of survival. In other cases, there is a barrier to freedom: authoritarianism that deprives citizens of their political freedom and basic civil rights. Some economists even understand that an authoritarian regime is desirable under the eyes of the economy because it means stability to allow for the optimum use and allocation of resources. However, the author says that in the history of mankind, hunger in society as a whole only took place under authoritarian regimes, which questions the quoted efficiency and favours freedom. Economically speaking, in Brazil, the dictatorship of Ernesto Geisel from 1974 to 1978 is an example of such growth policies; however, the economic growth was not sustainable due to the concentration of income and social differences. This is why, as Sen said, economic improvement does not mean development when matters related to freedom and quality of life are not considered. In other words, development must be the result of economic growth and an improvement in the quality of life. It must include ‘changes in the composition of the product and allocated resources in different sectors of the economy so as to improve the social and economic wellbeing indicators (poverty, unemployment, lack of equality, health, nourishment, education, and housing)’.64 Freedom as development is seen not only as a result of the process but also as the means chosen to reach growth. It must be seen as a part of the process to ensure development through freedom. Sen has 5.2. Levels of Freedom Economically speaking, freedom is linked to actions and decision-making as long as they are followed by freedom of opportunities. Freedom presupposes Notes 62 63 64 Sen, 28. Ibid., at 30. Marco Antonio Vasconcelos & Manuel Enriquez Garcia, Fundamentos de economia (São Paulo: Saraiva, 1998), 05. Global Trade and Customs Journal, Volume 6, Issue 7/8 © 2011 Kluwer Law International. 372 Marcia Carla Pereira Ribeiro & Eduardo Oliveira Agustinho freedom as a tool and as an end for directing public policies and private initiatives toward development. Lack of freedom antagonizes the priority of growth. Under this point of view, the poverty criterion should be replaced by the lack of capability that hinders the use of freedoms as a parameter to evaluate the level of development in a country. the denial of a free market would mean the destitution of freedom. The problem is not the idea of market but its general meaning that is associated with utilitarianism as a mere mechanism to increase wealth. 5.6. Individual and Social Freedom Sen argues that individual freedom is a social product because there are social dispositions that can enhance individual freedom. However, individual freedom has to be used not only to improve the life of each person but also to make social dispositions more adequate and efficient. Regarding tradition, culture, and democracy, the people who are involved must have the opportunity to choose the measures to be taken when tradition leads to poverty and death.65 5.4. Expanding Freedom Development as freedom is a set of substantive freedoms that represent the basic elements that are given to an individual so that, according to individual capabilities, one can exercise these freedoms. The increment of capability and the speed at which it is processed cannot be dissociated from public policies that are directed by the influence of individuals that make effective use of their capabilities in a cycle. In a democratically mature society, a cycle is established in which the widening of access to the benefits of growth leads to an improved education of the holder of the democratic power that will make choices based on the knowledge that was acquired, and they will elect agents that will multiply positive social policies. The facilitators, information, and technology are needed to reach the purpose of providing the individual freedom that can only be built on knowledge. In the sphere of the private world, the concept given by the author to an individual attitude is based on one being a member of the public and part of economic, social, and political transactions. The concern is to make the people more rational with a view that is more complex than materialistic attitudes based on personal satisfaction. The aim of Sen’s work is to present a new proposition for the development of an evaluation system based in substantive freedom. According to this approach, poverty stops being equivalent to low income and becomes the destitution of capacity. 5.7. Innovation and Technology as Sources of Development It was inferred previously, under the scope of development, that the expansion of freedom is a primary end and is, therefore, not only an element but also the main means of its instrumental role. Instrumental freedoms include political freedom (suffrage), economic (credit), social opportunities (education and health), assurance of transparency (licit relationships), and protective security (social safety). These freedoms tend to contribute to the general possibility that an individual can live more freely. They also complement one another. In a system of interrelationships that complement one another, development is the consequence of economic growth that allows private income to grow and a growing active intervention of the government to expand social services. According to Sen: According to multiple inter-related freedoms, there is the need to develop a sustainable plurality of institutions such as democratic systems, legal mechanisms, market, education and health, media and other kinds of communication etc. These institutions can incorporate private initiatives besides the public ones, as well as mixed structures such as non-governmental institutions and coops.66 5.5. Market and Freedom Based on all of the above ideas, the author tried to understand the meaning of a free market outside the context of usefulness and looked at it through the eyes of freedom, which, according to Sen, is the original reading that was later restricted by post-Smithian classic liberalism. It is valid to say that the freedom of a system can incrementally develop and accept certain restrictions, usually in the form of regulations. From this point of view, under the eyes of freedom, the precept of a free market is set forth by the fact that Therefore, development is freedom. Freedom cannot be dissociated from the use of capabilities. Capabilities build on the preservation of life, including the right to health and education. The access to knowledge is basic in the search for development. Notes 65 66 Sen, 47. Ibid., 71. 373 Global Trade and Customs Journal, Volume 6, Issue 7/8 © 2011 Kluwer Law International. Development and Innovation: The Role of State Enterprises In the current macro-economy, in the face of the international financial crisis that assumes the structural contours that bring change to the system, changes and innovation are the proper tools to overcome the capital reproduction system that collapsed in the beginning of the twenty-first century. The idea of a self-regulating market was shown to be ineffective mainly because of two reasons. First, because the market economy can only be successful in a society of markets, this logic subverts the premise that economic relationships should be based in social relationships as one is subordinated to the other.67 Second, because when market mechanisms and the elements of the industry (e.g., nature and work force) are inserted, the need to submit social interests to market laws becomes clear.68 Once we have identified the flaw in the self-regulating market theory, the idea that society is not limited to market relationships becomes evident. These relationships cannot aim for profit only because of the growth of worldwide recognition (1) of the need to change the current production-purchase model, (2) of the need to innovate and use technology that has a smaller impact on the environment, and (3) that sustainable development cannot be spoken of without being linked to the tripod ‘economy – environment – society’ as basic to political and social endeavours. The Australian business consultant Brian Bacon says that: refers to a natural path of capitalism: search for new technology and create new production models. However, it is not simple. Some sectors are to be replaced by others, what means to alternate from power to opportunity and the natural barrier is to stop, to make it more difficult to change. The ones who lose always try to prolong the old ways of making money and establishing power. OPEC last year had its turn trying to lower the price of petrol to suppress the search for renewable sources of energy. Nevertheless, the more the old system persists, the more we should prolong the crisis.71 When it comes to values, consumers with a materialist profi le inflict a rhythm to production that involves long working hours. It is up to each person to determine what constitutes development. Nevertheless, companies play the main role in the creation of a new system that integrates economy, ecology, and society because companies have never developed a sense of total responsibility. Now companies are recognizing their responsibility. People are worried about global warming, the environment, and what is going on in their cities. People are very conscious of the products they choose within their sense of what is good for the community and ecology. At the moment, this is why the companies have a more conscious behaviour.72 It is under this point of view that SCEs, who play the main role in the integration of private and public investment in innovation and technology, ensure the interest of the collectivity that is responsible for their existence. The real development depends on SCEs widening the access to information and new technology that will effectively improve the well-being of society. The examples of Copel and Embraer discussed above are great examples of state enterprises that invested in innovation and technology and were competitive without losing sight of the aimed development that provides a better quality of life in a fairer and more comfortable society. These cases show why there should be a redefinition of the subsidies policies for state enterprises as a tool for the promotion of development in harmony with the international trade. to some leaders and some companies, this crisis is an opportunity to innovate in a way never seen before and being closer to the client to understand deeply what is needed and create closer relationships with the employees.69 To support his line of thought, the consultant affirms that: nobody likes changes. It is more comfortable to do what one always did. People have the capability of changing, but they carry on doing the same thing. What crisis do is take away all options and alternatives and force one to see more clearly what is the real meaning of a business, what is truthful in a relationship with clients and employees and what really has to be kept and what is not needed.70 6. CONCLUSION The way out of this crisis and towards development lies in innovation, which includes a better use of resources, and the re-evaluation of values. The first Over the last several years, a deep change in the economic paradigms has occurred. Gradually, the search Notes 67 68 69 70 71 72 Karl Polanyi, The Great Transformation: The Political & Economic Origins of Our Time, 2nd edn (Boston: Beacon Press, 2001), 60. Ibid., at 74–75. Felipe Laufer, ‘Não se pode jogar uma crise no lixo’, Gazeta do Povo, Conjuntura, 08 Mar. 2009, <http://portal.rpc.com.br/gazetadopovo/ economia/conteudo. phtml?tl=1&id=864723&tit=Nao-se-pode-jogar-uma-crise-no-lixo>, viewed on 20 Mar. 2009. Ibid. Christian Luiz da Silva, ‘2009: da crise ao desenvolvimento’, Gazeta do Povo, Opinião, 09 Mar. 2009, 2. See Laufer. Global Trade and Customs Journal, Volume 6, Issue 7/8 © 2011 Kluwer Law International. 374 Marcia Carla Pereira Ribeiro & Eduardo Oliveira Agustinho development that cannot be dissociated from current societies. Because a model of development based on the systematic exclusion of a large part of the population is no longer acceptable, the SCE catches the eye of private investment, and at the same time, it is a great tool for the promotion of social fairness because the company’s inherent social responsibility is a certification of quality and, therefore, shares a profit. Currently, to keep the company competitively in the market, the social commitment that justifies this entrepreneurship is an asset to the investment in innovation and new technology. Therefore, there can be no doubt of the need to rethink the SCM Agreement in the Multilateral Trade System to allow subsidies to be considered not only because of its adverse effects but also because of the virtue of its purposes, which includes an understanding of the current social and economic role of SCEs in the face of the new ideology of sustainable development. for efficiency at any cost is being left behind, and the dichotomy of capital and work is being overcome. Currently, it is accepted that only the existence in an environment that is truly cooperative reaches higher levels of well-being. On this account, the state and the market are intimate in a way never imagined by classic liberalism and the self-regulating criterion. The financial crisis that settled in North America under the premise of a global economy now has its hands in developed and developing countries, and the state is being called upon to intervene and bring the market back to normality. One way that the state can intervene is through SCEs that play an important role in the increment of new technology and social inclusion. When public and private investments ally, these enterprises propel economic and social development while having in mind, at all times, the interest of the collectivity that justifies their existence. In other words, the SCEs offer its entrepreneurship to the interest of the collectivity that values as relevant or essential the search for social well-being and 375 Global Trade and Customs Journal, Volume 6, Issue 7/8 © 2011 Kluwer Law International. KLUWER LAW INTERNATIONAL QUERY LOG File Name GTCJ_0607 Authors Marcia Carla Pereira Ribeiro & Eduardo Oliveira Agustinho Query No. Query 1 Please provide the complete title of cases at first citation, if any. 2 Please check if changes made to ‘The third part deals with the limits that are imposed by the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (hereinafter ‘SCM Agreements’), which establishes policies for state enterprises in the pursuit of development, and this contradicts the aim of the document’ retained the intended meaning of the sentence. 3 Please check if references provided in foreign language were captured correctly. 4 This sentence seems vague: ‘If private investment is to be privileged, the company must be led to favour the investment that will not occur unless there is a forecasted profit that is associated to the public investment, which is not necessarily directed to profit but is relevant to the interest of the collectivity or a matter of national safety that justifies the state enterprise.’ Please make necessary changes, if any. 5 Please check if ‘According to clause 2º, caput, the authorized companies must apply, every year, the minimum amount of 1% of revenues in research and development of the electric power sector, excluding, because of exemption, companies that generate energy exclusively from wind, solar, biomass, small hydroelectric power plants and qualified co-generation’ is correct. Author Remarks