Efficiency in tax collection: evidence from Brazilian municipalities Paulo Arvate1 and Enlinson Mattos2 This paper assesses and tests the efficiency in tax collection in 3,359 Brazilian municipalities. First, applying a non-parametric methodology - Free Disposable Hull, we compute comparative efficiency scores for each municipality. In particular, given an individual amount of capital an, labor treated as inputs, we evaluate efficiency in producing two outputs: amount of per capita local tax collected (tax revenue) and the size of local informal economy (tax evasion). Second, controlling for spatial interaction, the paper also investigates the factors that influence that efficiency score. The results suggest that the federal and state transfer to municipalities (flypaper effect) and local public expenditure per-capita are negatively associated with their ranking. Keywords: Efficiency, Tax collection, Informal economy, FDH, spatial econometrics JEL: H20, H21, C67, C14, C31. 1 2 CEPESP and EESP - Getulio Vargas Foundation, e-mail: [email protected]. CEPESP and EESP - Getulio Vargas Foundation, e-mail:[email protected].. 1. Introduction One of the main problems of tax implementation faced by developing countries is the size of informal economy. The tax burden falls over a relative small fraction of the economy, while many individuals resist contributing to the government tax collection by opting out to the formal sector. It is true that, sometimes these individuals do not find work elsewhere, but it may also happen that skilled workers want to pay less tax.3 This phenomenon is also noticed by the media. In May of 2006 in the Business Weak Magazine, Diana Farrel, Mackinsey´s consultant, argues that: “Informal business, even large ones, choose you stay that way if there is a change in the factors that generally drive them into the informality: high corporate tax and the bureaucratic burden of operating formally. In developing countries, only about half of total tax revenue is paid by registered businesses (with the rest contributed by individuals).” 4 Usually, the issue of the tax collection efficiency is concerned with the maximization of tax revenue instead of minimizing the size of informal economy. There is an obvious trade-off between maximizing tax revenue and minimizing the size of informal economy. Since tax collection comes from the formal sector, governments are willing not to sacrifice this sector. Therefore the optimal alternative to finance expenditures is to reduce the shadow economy. Although the relation between tax collection efficiency and size of informal economy has not been accurately explored, Bajada (2007), Schneider and Klinglmair (2004), Dell´Anno and Schneider (2003), Schneider and Enste (2000), Giles and Caragata (1998) and Giles (1998) explore the relation between tax burden and informal (shadow) economy. However, Giles (1999) estimating the New Zealand’s Tax-Gap, attempts to measure the loss in tax collection on the part of that government due to the growth of the informality in that country. In contrast, the objective of the paper is twofold. First, to investigate the efficiency scores of tax collection in the municipalities in terms of amount of percapita local tax collected (tax revenue) and the size of informal economy (tax evasion). Second, we attempt to verify the factors that are associated with that efficiency score. This work contributes to the literature when includes the size of informal economy as 3 This decision is of course dependent on the size of the government and consequently the tax imposed as well the individual’s earnings. See also Strand (2001) for informality only at the top of income distribution. 4 See also Kenyon and Kapaz (2005). an item in the tax collection efficiency score.5. It also advances to test the factors that are correlated with that score, in particular, municipality’s characteristics (ideology of the mayors, technology, expenses) and residents’ characteristics (age, income and wealth), taking into consideration spatial effects. The results suggest that the federal and state transfers to municipalities are negatively associated with their ranking. This leads to a reinterpretation of the flypaper effect. Higher transfers are associated with less efficiency in local tax collection and reduction of local informal sector. Also, technology implementation improves efficiency. In addition, we find that higher income per-capita is related to more efficiency in informal sector reduction but also to less efficiency in local tax collection per-capita Brazilian municipalities represent an interesting sample. First, Brazil is in the “eye” of the hurricane in terms of size of the tax revenue and the informal economy. The total tax burden has approached to forty percent (40%) of the GDP in the 2006 (Ipeadata, 2006) and the size of the shadow economy, represents more than thirty five percent (35%) of the official GDP in 2000 (Schneider and Klinglmair, 2004). Second, the Brazilian municipalities present a uniform tax, contract worker and company openings legislation.6 The next section lays out the technique used to measure the efficiency score (Free Disposable Hull) and the empirical model necessary to estimate the factors correlated with the two measures of efficiency used to rank the municipalities (tax revenue of the formal sector and the size of formality). Section 3 presents the results and the last section concludes. 2. Empirical Implementation 2.1 Efficiency Scores The first step is to compute the efficiency scores of each municipality. To obtain such efficiency indicator is necessary to determine the inputs and the outputs of the municipality and then compare them (both input and output) to each other. That produces a score of the position for each unit. They are input and output efficiency 5 The efficiency score is usually computed for public expenditures. For instance ,see Gupta e Verhoeven (2001), Afonso e Aubyn (2004), Herrera e Pang(2005), Afonso, Schuknecht e Tanzi(2005), Tandon (2005), Afonso e Fernandes (2003), Brunet (2006) e Souza, Cribari-Neto e Stosic (2005). 6 Although the municipalities could decide on tax rate, fines and exemptions, all municipalities have basically two taxes by the federal law: the service tax (ISS) and the residential property tax (IPTU). In addition, the legislation for contract workers and opening of companies is federal. scores whose range goes from 0 to 1. Every municipality on the Production Possibility Frontier receive the maximum score 1. These are relative efficiency scores. For instance, the input efficiency score of a unit means how much less input could be used to obtain the same level of output. Similarly, the output efficiency score calculates how much more output could be produced given the amount of input. This paper utilizes Free Disposable Hull (FDH) methodology to compute those scores7. FDH is a non-parametric technique proposed by Deprins, Simar e Tulkens(1984). The major advantages of FDH analysis is that it imposes only weak assumptions on the production technology but still allows for comparison of efficiency levels among producers. It is necessary to assume that reduction of the inputs (outputs) with the same technology maintaining the output (input) fixed cross municipalities are made. The production set is not necessarily convex. That guarantees the existence of a continuous FDH which is going to be used as a dependent variable to identify the best practices in government tax collection to asses what are the factors that increase (relative) efficiency. Therefore, to determine the efficiency score using FDH analysis, assume n municipalities, m products/services produced by those governments with k inputs. In terms of production function y i = F ( xi ), i = 1...n (1) where y mx1 is the ouput vector and x kx1 corresponds to the input vector. One can rank the municipality i if it is not the most efficient in terms of input MIN i = n1,....,nl MAX j =1,....,m x j (n) x j (i ) (2) and n1 ,....., nl are l municipalities more efficient than municipality i. Similarly, in terms of output, municipality i can be ranked in relation to the most efficient 7 Two other methodologies are also used in the literature. First, Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) is also non-parametric and builds envelops from the efficient points on the frontier differently from the FDH explained above. See, for instance Afonso and St. Aubyn (2004) and Herrera and Pang (2005) and Sousa, Cribari-Neto, Stosic and Borko (2005). Second, a parametric approach denominated stochastic frontier computes the frontier using regression techniques. This method assumes error distributions. See Greene (2003). MAX i = n1,....,nl MIN j =1,....,m y j (n) y j (i ) (3) The procedure can be summarized as follows. First a producer is selected. Then all producers that are more efficient than it are marked. For every pair of producers containing the unit under analysis and the more efficient one is computed a score for each input (dividing the input of the unit under analysis and the more efficient one). Then select the more efficient producer that bring the unit under analysis closest to the frontier. The calculation of the input efficiency score can be illustrated with an example. Suppose 3 producers with a 2-input 2-output case. A(20, 33; 15, 10), B(19, 30, 16,12), C(25, 32 ; 16, 11). The first two numbers denotes inputs while the last two numbers yield outputs. A is less efficient than B -A uses more of both inputs while its outputs is smaller. However C is not more efficient than A. The input score for A can be calculated in the table below. Observe that since C is not compared to neither A and B, it gets score equal to 1. B also receives 1 because it is more efficient than A and there is no other municipality more efficient than it is. Table 1 – Example Several studies have used FDH analysis to asses the government spending efficiency. Vanden Eeckaut, Tulkens and Jamar (1993) establish the relative efficiency municipalities for Belgium. Gupta and Verhoeven (2001) consider the efficiency in education and health expenditures for Africa countries. In contrast this paper studies the tax collection efficiency for Brazilian municipalities and what are the factors the influence such ranking. 2.2 Regression Analysis In fitting a regression plane using municipalities’ data, one has to take into consideration the possible spatial interaction of the variables. The most intuitive criterion for selecting neighbors within a local government context is based upon geographical proximity, and this paper is going to focus on contiguity (rook criteria).8 Within our model this is particularly reasonable since the municipalities are sensitive to neighboring jurisdictions for two reasons (as argued in Besley and Case 1995). First, 8 Results for Euclidian distance of the municipalities and queen criteria are available upon request. they experience similar shocks in the economy and second, the information about the nearby jurisdictions is likely to spread out.9 Therefore our base model is Y = WYδ + Xβ + u (4) where Y is a (nx1) vector of municipal efficiency scores. X is (nxk) matrix. In our case k=17 (with the constant). W is a (nxn) matrix with the weights of neighbors’ municipalities. The equation (4) also points out that any estimation by OLS will represent a biased estimation of the coefficients. Neighbors may also be subject to correlated random shocks that cannot be attributed to the spillover causality which can imply wrong inferences. Therefore, I also check the possibility of a model that allows for possible correlation among the errors of neighboring. Y = Xβ + u u = ρWu + ε (5) where ξ ~ N (0, σ 2 ) . Even though estimation of (5) by OLS is not biased, it is not consistent. Then a correction of the covariance matrix will improve the estimation. 2.3 Data 2.3.1 FDH data Inputs are defined as capital, labor and the combination of them. 10 As “proxy” of the capital (K), capital investments per-capita from 1980 and 2004 are accumulated and depreciated by the rate of 3% at each year. 11 As “proxy” of the labor (L) we use the number of both indirect and direct public works per capita in the municipalities. We use two measures of output of the ´´production function´´ of the government: local tax revenue (T) and the proportion of formal sector (inf). The amount of local tax per-capita collected is used for the first variable while the proportion of formal workers in the total workers (excluding self-employers and employers) as a “proxy” of the size of the formal sector. 12 With this choice, we aim to see the two sides of the same coin: efficient 9 See also Anselin (1988). In addition, the total municipality’s expenditures per capita is used as input. The results are worse than shown here and are available upon request. 11 We test alternatives rates of depreciation: 5% e 8%. The results are similar. 12 There is a distinction between formal (CLT) and informal workers in Brazil. The informal workers do not have the legal right of job tenure. We could say that their job tenure is more precarious than that of formal workers. The expression ‘CLT’ has its origin in Law 5452 of May of 1943, entitled the 10 municipalities will be the ones that have more tax revenue but also a higher participation of the formal sector in the total municipality economy.13 2.3.2 Regression Data To identify possible variable associated with the differences in efficiency of tax collected among the municipalities we select: a. Ideology – Despite the literature mention the effect of the ideology of the governments on the taxation, that is not done relating ideology and tax revenue efficiency and informality together. Messere (1993) argues that center-right governments generally tend to choose a total tax burden lower directing it for a composition where more consumer taxes predominate of what income taxes. On the other hand, left-wing governments tend to favor a higher size of the government which implies a higher tax burden, where more income tax predominates over consumption tax. Pommerehne and Scheneider (1983) analyzes Australia during the decade of 70 and argues that right-wing governments tend to have less direct taxes and a lower tax/GDP ratio, while left-wing governments tend to have more indirect taxes and a higher tax/GDP ratio. We use the ideological classification of the parties of the mayors for 2004 (Pesquisa de Informações Básicas Municipais of the IBGE) following the classification proposed by Coppedge (1997). Two dummies are used to represent the ideology. The parties classified as center-left and left are denominated by the variable left (left) and the parties from center-right and right are denoted as right (right). b. Technology - As Sousa et al (2005) argue from the expenditure view, the technology helps to increase efficiency. We use two dummy variables as “proxy” of the existence of technology: tax service data set computerized (ISSinform) and the services from municipalities to contributors through Internet, portal or web-page (serint, source: Pesquisa de Informações Básicas Municipais, IBGE , 2004 )14. c. Fiscal impacts - Certainly a municipality that has an expense level higher searches for a higher level of tax revenue. That could lead to higher tax collection efficiency.15 On the other hand, more transfers to the municipalities from either the federal or state Consolidation of Labor Laws (CLT in Portuguese). This law establishes the rules of labor relations in the private sector. 13 The data used to build the variable tax-collect was taken from Ipeadata (2004). The variable that captures informality (inf) is taken from the CENSO (2000). 14 We also test the possibility of residential property tax data set computerized (IPTUinform) and the results show that this variable is not significant. 15 The literature shows only that higher governments are more inefficient on expenditures. See Herrera and Pang (2005) and Afonso, Schuknecht and Tanzi (2005). government, might imply in more incentives to spend (flypaper effect). Consequently, lower is the incentive to search for efficiency. We construct two variables to capture these effects. We consider the local expenditure per capita (exp). To observe the effect of the transfers into the model, we include the transfers per capita of both the state and municipal governments (transf). The data of expenditure and transferences are taken from Ipeadata (2004)16 and the population data is extracted from the Pesquisa de Informações Básicas Municipais (IBGE, 2004). d. Characteristics of the municipalities – To control for territorial differences in the municipalities, we use the followings variables: the percentage of urban population over resident population (urb), the population density (density) and percentage of people with electric energy in their residence (eletr), the percentage of people employed (Economically Active Population divided by the Working Age Population - emp), the percentage of resident doctors for a thousand inhabitants (doctor) and the cost of transport of the Municipal Headquarters until the nearest State Capital (transport). With exception of the transport cost (Ipeadata, 1995), the data are taken from Ipeadata (2000). e. Characteristics of the residents – To cite as example of how these characteristics matter in Brazil, it is very common to observe pensioner exemption in the Imposto Predial e Territorial Urbano (IPTU - the most important urban territorial tax collected from the municipalities). Or as Rodríguez (2004) argues: ´´the bargain between groups of interest and politicians on exemptions taxes implies that individuals with high income do not pay taxes” (p.957). To identify these characteristics of the contributors we use the percentage of people with more than sixty five years in the municipality living alone (old), percentage of residents in the municipality with a computer (compu), percentage of poor people in the municipality (poverty) and income per capita (Inc.). The data are taken from Ipeadata, 2000. The Table 2 summarizes the Descriptive Statistics. 3. Results 3.1. Efficiency score results Table 3 presents the summary statistics of the efficiency score for each state17. As explained above, we compute six efficiency scores: three input-related and three output16 Site: www.ipeadata.gov.br The full table is available upon request. Results concerning administrative costs instead of the pair capital and labor as input are also available upon request. 17 related. The difference among them is the output. In the first two columns the output considered is local tax collected percapita (T), the next two columns regard the output equal to the size of formal economy, and the oher two columns take into consideration both outputs. The last column presents the municipalities that are efficient in, at least, one criterion. There are some characteristics interesting in the data. The results suggest that a large number of efficient cities in the South of Brazil (Sao Paulo, Minas Gerais, Espirito Santo, Rio de Janeiro, Parana, Santa Catarina and Rio Grande do Sul). Also, 82% of the states that have efficient cities include their capital as one of them. Sao Paulo state, the richest and more developed one, has 25 cities classified as efficient, while Rio Grande do Sul has 18 and Santa Catarina 15. In most of the cases, when states out of the South region allocate an efficient city, that one is the capital. (approximately (70%)). Piaui, the poorest state, has no efficient city while Maranhao, the second poorest, has two, and one of them is the capital, Sao Luis. For instance, the results show that ninety five (95) municipalities present at least one type of efficiency (input or output and three different outputs: tax collection, size of local informal economy and both). Almost fifteen per cent (13 out of 95) are capitals of the states. Among those, only four can be considered efficient in all criterions used (Rio Branco, Belém, Salvador and Porto Alegre). Other municipalities such as Manacapuru (Amazonas), Rorainópolis (Roraima), Bacabal (Maranhão), Vila Velha (Espirito Santo) and São João de Miriti (Rio de Janeiro) are also efficient in all criterions.18 In order to better design public policies to improve tax collection efficiency, we relate the computed efficiency rankings with possible explanatory variables, described below. 3.2. Regression Results Before using traditional regression methods, it is necessary to check if there exists spatial interaction between the computed efficiency scores. For instance, the fact that one jurisdiction is relatively efficient, that might influence the behavior and practices of neighborhood jurisdictions in order to improve tax collection methods. Table 4 presents unconditional Moran´s I statistics for these scores and confirms that suspect, i.e., we cannot accept the hypothesis of non-spatial covariance among the 18 See table 2. efficient scores. Tables 5-8 in the linear regression columns also reinforce that, even conditional; the above hypothesis cannot be accepted (See Moran´s I statistic, LMerror and LMlag tests). In particular, the tests suggest a positive spatial correlation among municipalities efficiency scores. We divide the regressions results according to assumptions on which variables are input and which ones are output. Cases 1-3 assume that the Inputs are capital and labor while case 4 considers the average score of inputs, outputs or both. Moreover, Case 1 considers only per-capita local tax collection, Case 2 takes into consideration the size of formal local economy as the output and Case 3 combines both outputs.19 Case 1 – Output (T): Local tax collected per-capita. Table 5 presents the result for the Case1. It shows that the likelihood of the spatial error model is higher in both input and output-oriented scores. Therefore we focus the analysis in those columns. Not surprisingly, the variables that capture technology (ISSinf and servint) in the process of tax collection are positively associated with relative the efficiency scores. More importantly, the level of local expenditure percapita (exp) and transfers (transf) to municipalities (federal and state) is negatively related with their efficiency ranking. In particular, a one real (R$) increase in per-capita terms is associated with a 0,00003 decrease in the relative efficiency score. This last outcome can be reinterpreted as the ´new flypaper effect´, as it says that higher transfers are associated with less efficiency. Note that this result holds for every possibility of input and output. Income per-capita (inc) and poverty also relates negatively with tax collection efficiency. This might reflect the fact that when there is a large fraction of the population below the poverty line, they also have less information about government spending. Then, richer individuals could benefit from more inefficient methods of tax collection, since they are the ones who pay the tax. In addition to that, the inclusion of political variables suggests that center mayor’s party is more efficient than right or leftwing ones. Last, municipalities located too far from the its state´s capital (transpo) tend to be less efficient (coefficient equals to -0,00005). 19 Selected models are dashed and statistically significant variables are in bold letters. Case 2 – Output(I): Size of Formal Local Economy When we consider a different output, which is the size of local formal economy, we find surprising results. As opposed to the Case 1, the likelihood of the spatial error model is lower in both input and output-oriented scores than spatial lag modes. We only discuss the results concerning the last ones. First, table 6 shows that the variables income (inc) and poverty change theirs signs. Now they are positively associated with the computed efficiency score. That means that richer municipalities (high per -capita income) relates to higher efficiency in universalizing tax payment (reduction in informal economy) rather than to increase tax collection. Similarly, higher levels of local public expenditures per-capita (exp), now is related to higher efficient scores. Municipalities that spend a lot, try to increase the efficiency to collect from the informal sector. Second, as expected, urbanization (urb) and residence density (density) is correlated with higher efficiency in reduction the informal sector. And last, technology (+), transfers (-) and distance from the state´s capital (-) have the same sign. Case 3 – Outputs(T+I): Local tax collected per-capita and Size of Formal Local Economy. Table 7 concerns the result where the local governments have multiple objectives: increase local tax collection per-capita and decrease local informal sector. The spatial lag model is chosen for the input-oriented case while the spatial error model is selected for the output-oriented one. The variables concerning technology (ISSinf and servint), transfers (transf), urbanization (urb), distance from state´s capital (transpo) have the same sign as before (+,-,+,-). The difference here is that neither income per-capita (inc) nor local public expenditure per-capita (exp) is statistically significant, while poverty is negative and significant only for the output-oriented situation. This might reflect the conflict between the two objectives and their relation to these variables. Case 4 - Average Input Scores, Average Output Scores, Total Average Scores This case attempts to compute how the explanatory variables are related to the average input, average output and total average scores. We find similar results concerning the following variables: technology (ISSinf and servint), transfers (transf), urbanization (urb), distance from state´s capital (transpo). Income per-capita (inc) is not significant while poverty is significant only in the last two models. Local public expenditure per-capita (exp) is statistically significant (and negatively related to the efficiency score) only in the average input score model. Political variables, in particular right-wing mayor´s party (right), is related to less efficient average output and total average scores. Similarly, the proportion of old-age persons in the community (old) is negatively related to the average output and total average efficiency scores. 4. Conclusion This paper assesses and tests the efficiency in tax collection in 3,359 Brazilian municipalities. First, applying a non-parametric methodology - FDH (Free Disposable Hull), we compute the efficiency scores for each municipality comparing to each other. Second, controlling for spatial interaction, the paper also investigates the factors that influence that efficiency score. The results suggest that the federal and state transfers to municipalities are negatively associated with their ranking. This leads to a reinterpretation of the flypaper effect. Higher transfers are associated with less efficiency in local tax collection and reduction of local informal sector. Also, technology implementation improves efficiency. In addition, we find that higher income per-capita is related to more efficiency in informal sector reduction but also to less efficiency in local tax collection per-capita. References Afonso, A. and Schuknecht, L. and Tanzi,V. (2005) Public sector efficiency: an international comparison. Public Choice number 123, pp 321-347. Afonso, A. and Aubyn, M.S. (2004) Non-parametric Approaches to Education and Health expenditure Efficiency in OECD countries. Working Paper, Technical University of Lisbon. Afonso, A. and Fernandes, S. (2003) Efficiency of Local Government Spending: Evidence for the Lisbon Region. Working Paper, Technical University of Lisbon. Anselin, L. (1988), Spatial Econometrics: Methods and Models, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht, The Netherlands. Bajada C. (2002) How Reliable are Estimates of the Underground Economy? Economics Bulletin, Vol. 3, No. 14 pp. 1-11. Besley, T. and Case, A. (1995), Incumbent Behavior: Vote seeking, Tax setting, and Yardstick competition, American Economic Review, 85, 25-45. Brunet, J. F.G. and Borges, C. and Bertê, A.M. and Bussatto, L. and Brunet, L. (2006) Estados comparados por funções do orçamento – uma avaliação da eficiência e efetividade dos gastos públicos estaduais. Prêmio Menção Honrosa IPEACAIXA. Coppedge, M. (1997). A Classification of Latin American Political Parties. The Helen Kellogg Institute for International Studies, Working Paper Series # 244. (http:// http://www.nd.edu/%7Ekellogg/WPS/244.pdf) Dell´Anno, R. and Scneider, F. (2003) The Shadow Economy of Italy and other OECD countries: What do we know? Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice. Deprins, D., Simar, L. and Tulkens H. (1984), Measuring labor-efficiency in postoffices. In: M. Marchand, P. Pestiau and H. Tulkens (Eds), The performance of public enterprises: concepts and measurement. Amestrdan: North Holand. Giles, D.E. (1998). The underground economy: minimizing the size of government. Department of Economics, University of Victoria. Giles, D.E. (1999) Modeling the hidden economy and the tax gap in New Zealand. Department of Economics, University of Victoria.. Giles, D.E. and Caragata, P.J. (1998). The learning Path of the Hidden Economy: Tax and growth effects in New Zealand. Department of Economics, University of Victoria. Gupta, S. and Verhoeven, M. (2001), The efficiency of government expenditure. Experiences from Africa. Journal of Policy Modelling, 23, 433 - 467. Greene, W. H. (2003). Econometric Analysis. Prentice Hall. Fifth Edition. Herrera, S. and Pang, G. (2005) Efficiency of Public Spending in Developing Countries: An Efficiency Frontier Approach. World Bank Policy Research, Working Paper 3645. Ipeadata, 1995, 2000, 2004, 2005. Data from Instituto de pesquisa econômica aplicada (IPEA), Ministério do Planejamento. www.ipeadata.gov.br. Kaufmann, D. and Kaliberda, A. (1996) Integrating the unofficial economy into dynamics of post socialist economies: a framework of analyses and evidence, in B. Kaminski (ed). Economic Transition in Rússia and the New States of Eurásia, London: M.E. Sharpe, pp81-120. Kenyon, T. and Kapaz, E. (2005) The informality Trap. The World Bank Group: Public Policy for the Private Sector. Messere, K. (1993). Tax Policy in OECD Countries: Choices and Conflicts. The Netherlands: IBFD Publications BV. Pesquisa de Informações Básicas Municipais, Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística (IBGE) , 2004. Pommerehne, W.W. and Schneider, W. (1983). Does government in a representative democracy follow a majority of voters’ preferences: An empirical examination. In H. Hanush (Ed.), Anatomy of government deficiencies, 61–88. Berlin-Heidelberg: Springer Verlag. Rodriguez, F. (2004) Inequality, Redistribution, and Rent-Seeking. Economics and Politics, volume 16, number 3, pages 954-1985. Sousa M. da C. S.and Cribari-Neto, F. and Stosic, B.(2005), Explaining DEA Technical Efficiency Scores in a Outlier Corrected Environment: The case of Public Service in Brazilian Municipalities. Brazilian Review of Econometrics, number 2, pp. 289-315 Schneider, F and Klinglmair, R. (2004) Shadow Economies around the world: What do we know? Paper presented in the Public Choice Meeting 2004 in Baltimore (USA). Schneider, F. and Enste, D.H. (2000) Shadow Economies: Size, Causes, and Consequences. Journal of Economic Literature, vol. XXXVIII, pages: 77-114. Strand, Jon (2001). Tax distortions, household production and black-market work. (mimeo). Tandon, A. (2005) Measuring Efficiency of Macro Systems: An application to Millennium Development Goal Attainment. ERD Working Paper series number 66. Asian Development Bank. Tanzi, V. (1980) Underground Economy and tax evasion in the United States: estimates and implications. International Monetary Fund. Vanden Eeckaut, P., Tulkens H. and Jamar M.-A (1993), Cost-efficiency in Belgian municipalities, In H. Fried, C.A. Knox Lovell, and S. Schmidt (Eds), The Measuremtn of Productive Efficency: Techniques and Applications. New York: Oxford Univ. Press. Tables Table 1: Descriptive Statistics Min. 1st Q Median Mean 3rd Q Max. Min. 1st Q Median Mean 3rd Q Max. Min. 1st Q Median Mean 3rd Q Max. Input: K,L (T) output (Tax) Input: K,L(I) output (I) Input: K,L(I,T) output (I,T) Input (Avg) output (Avg) 0.017 0.150 0.248 0.282 0.365 1.000 Exp 102.100 436.600 582.700 677.100 806.200 6327.100 ISSinform 0.000 0.000 1.000 0.696 1.000 1.000 0.010 0.299 0.468 0.483 0.649 1.000 transf 193.100 533.700 689.000 819.700 967.900 7775.900 IPTUinform 0.000 1.000 1.000 0.885 1.000 1.000 0.017 0.159 0.259 0.294 0.383 1.000 old 0.056 10.336 12.986 13.054 15.671 28.698 servint 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.300 1.000 1.000 0.000 0.037 0.066 0.126 0.135 1.000 urb 0.000 43.200 62.740 61.410 81.090 100.000 left 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.353 1.000 1.000 0.017 0.170 0.273 0.322 0.412 1.000 density 0.082 12.920 26.030 119.500 54.040 12700.000 poverty 0.639 6.992 14.024 20.807 34.198 75.621 0.015 0.312 0.488 0.504 0.680 1.000 eletr 17.430 87.920 96.580 90.340 99.250 100.000 doctor 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.325 0.526 7.273 0.017 0.164 0.264 0.299 0.387 1.000 compu 0.002 0.998 2.621 3.962 5.445 41.405 transport 0.000 221.300 376.000 428.700 542.400 5949.000 0.014 0.222 0.346 0.371 0.493 1.000 emp 0.250 0.508 0.562 0.561 0.606 0.932 right 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.401 1.000 1.000 Average score 0.040 0.212 0.295 0.335 0.415 1.000 inc 30.430 107.510 186.530 192.240 250.050 954.650 Table 2: Efficient Scores by both Total and State sample Sample (observations) Total (3359) Amapá(37) Acre (15) Amazonas (42) Roraima (9) Pará (22) Amapá (3) Tocantins (50) Maranhão (47) Piauí (85) Ceará (115) Rio Grande do Norte (93) Paraíba (105) Pernambuco (122) Input: K,L (I) Output (I) Input: K,L (T) Output (T) Input: K,L (T+I) Output (T+I) min 0.017 0.010 0.017 0.000 0.017 0.015 max 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 mean 0.282 0.483 0.294 0.126 0.322 0.504 std 0.185 0.236 0.189 0.168 0.215 0.243 min 0.063 0.091 0.063 0.009 0.063 0.108 max 0.930 0.882 0.930 0.738 0.930 0.882 mean 0.327 0.466 0.300 0.095 0.333 0.472 std 0.202 0.192 0.193 0.137 0.206 0.191 min 0.065 0.034 0.065 0.001 0.065 0.038 max 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 mean 0.198 0.350 0.198 0.081 0.198 0.352 std 0.231 0.232 0.231 0.255 0.231 0.231 min 0.048 0.045 0.048 0.008 0.048 0.057 max 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 mean 0.183 0.251 0.199 0.077 0.199 0.257 std 0.166 0.182 0.184 0.195 0.184 0.184 min 0.103 0.216 0.135 0.049 0.135 0.216 max 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 mean 0.395 0.470 0.402 0.282 0.402 0.521 std 0.268 0.246 0.261 0.339 0.261 0.254 min 0.027 0.034 0.040 0.005 0.040 0.039 max 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 mean 0.228 0.335 0.252 0.117 0.256 0.351 std 0.206 0.241 0.202 0.205 0.201 0.238 min 0.265 0.182 0.265 0.088 0.265 0.219 max 0.657 0.714 0.657 0.115 0.657 0.733 mean 0.441 0.488 0.424 0.100 0.441 0.506 std 0.199 0.275 0.206 0.014 0.199 0.263 min 0.017 0.065 0.017 0.001 0.017 0.081 max 0.561 0.831 0.594 0.524 0.594 0.842 mean 0.174 0.263 0.202 0.078 0.206 0.286 std 0.118 0.146 0.135 0.089 0.142 0.148 min 0.047 0.015 0.047 0.000 0.047 0.031 max 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 mean 0.348 0.251 0.367 0.106 0.367 0.263 std 0.225 0.210 0.251 0.214 0.251 0.217 min 0.028 0.011 0.028 0.007 0.028 0.032 max 0.614 0.739 0.834 0.538 0.834 0.850 mean 0.222 0.201 0.236 0.043 0.236 0.211 std 0.152 0.135 0.171 0.062 0.171 0.138 min 0.036 0.013 0.036 0.006 0.036 0.029 max 0.572 0.794 0.799 0.762 0.960 0.831 mean 0.228 0.254 0.239 0.059 0.241 0.264 std 0.126 0.137 0.139 0.082 0.145 0.135 min 0.032 0.071 0.032 0.009 0.032 0.080 max 0.768 0.984 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 mean 0.226 0.384 0.240 0.068 0.243 0.396 std 0.121 0.162 0.140 0.107 0.138 0.166 min 0.024 0.012 0.030 0.006 0.030 0.029 max 0.555 0.839 0.722 0.511 0.722 0.839 mean 0.246 0.315 0.256 0.052 0.258 0.324 std 0.098 0.170 0.103 0.054 0.103 0.167 min 0.034 0.015 0.034 0.005 0.034 0.043 Alagoas (73) Sergipe (45) Bahia (154) Minas Gerais (503) Espírito Santo (58) Ro de Janeiro (62) São Paulo (460) Paraná (308) Santa Catarina (252) Rio Grande do Sul (388) Mato Grosso do Sul (69) Mato Grosso (72) Goiás (146) max 0.988 0.966 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 mean 0.327 0.382 0.325 0.074 0.335 0.390 std 0.152 0.216 0.146 0.113 0.157 0.216 min 0.066 0.023 0.066 0.001 0.066 0.029 max 0.676 0.824 0.676 0.594 0.676 0.848 mean 0.286 0.364 0.291 0.048 0.293 0.369 std 0.118 0.155 0.117 0.075 0.118 0.155 min 0.024 0.104 0.045 0.008 0.045 0.114 max 1.000 1.000 0.621 0.448 1.000 1.000 mean 0.251 0.403 0.249 0.070 0.267 0.419 std 0.203 0.198 0.150 0.085 0.205 0.205 min 0.024 0.057 0.055 0.005 0.055 0.068 max 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 mean 0.290 0.366 0.316 0.095 0.317 0.383 std 0.146 0.176 0.160 0.140 0.160 0.187 min 0.022 0.010 0.031 0.000 0.031 0.015 max 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 mean 0.302 0.453 0.305 0.090 0.325 0.469 std 0.166 0.229 0.154 0.120 0.184 0.235 min 0.023 0.182 0.023 0.015 0.023 0.187 max 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 mean 0.298 0.537 0.309 0.131 0.338 0.554 std 0.162 0.186 0.160 0.176 0.192 0.195 min 0.030 0.297 0.051 0.027 0.051 0.297 max 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 mean 0.328 0.652 0.411 0.305 0.436 0.710 std 0.257 0.172 0.264 0.287 0.281 0.178 min 0.020 0.170 0.024 0.008 0.024 0.187 max 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 mean 0.332 0.640 0.416 0.261 0.438 0.677 std 0.202 0.180 0.246 0.251 0.258 0.194 min 0.019 0.102 0.024 0.014 0.024 0.122 max 0.982 1.000 0.868 0.812 1.000 1.000 mean 0.228 0.532 0.227 0.092 0.245 0.548 std 0.152 0.168 0.142 0.091 0.167 0.169 min 0.029 0.045 0.041 0.018 0.041 0.067 max 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 mean 0.351 0.664 0.305 0.144 0.399 0.688 std 0.231 0.205 0.185 0.162 0.261 0.207 min 0.023 0.068 0.023 0.013 0.023 0.082 max 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 mean 0.285 0.633 0.229 0.121 0.318 0.652 std 0.230 0.206 0.180 0.137 0.250 0.205 min 0.042 0.036 0.045 0.017 0.045 0.042 max 0.504 0.822 0.866 0.457 0.866 0.833 mean 0.189 0.378 0.248 0.121 0.249 0.406 std 0.106 0.155 0.136 0.081 0.137 0.154 min 0.020 0.091 0.020 0.014 0.020 0.100 max 0.539 0.871 0.782 0.647 0.782 0.924 mean 0.160 0.393 0.206 0.119 0.208 0.420 std 0.108 0.166 0.141 0.103 0.144 0.168 min 0.039 0.023 0.039 0.020 0.039 0.029 max 0.690 0.896 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 mean 0.265 0.356 0.329 0.165 0.331 0.395 std 0.136 0.181 0.175 0.157 0.178 Table 3 - Efficient municipalities by state - Brazil States Efficient Municipalities in each state (type of score) Amapá Rio Branco ( I,T,T+I) Acre Manacapuru ( I,T,T+I) Amazonas Rorainópolis ( I,T,T+I) Roraima Belém ( I,T,T+I) Pará Amapá Tocantins Bacabal ( I,T,T+I) and São Luiz ( T,T+I) Maranhão Piauí Ceará Natal ( T,T+I) Rio Grande do Norte Paraíba Recife ( T,T+I) Pernambuco Alagoas Nossa Senhora do Socorro ( I,T+I) Sergipe Salvador ( I,T,T+I) Bahia Belo Horizonte ( T,T+I), Betim ( I,T+I), Itajubá ( T+I), Juiz de Fora ( T+I), Minas Gerais Espírito Santo Rio de Janeiro São Paulo Paraná Santa Catarina Rio Grande do Sul 0.192 Patos de Minas (T,T+I), Santa Luzia ( I,T+I), Santa Rita do Sapucaí ( I,T+I) and. São Gonçalo do Rio Abaixo (T,T+I). Vila Velha ( I,T,T+I) and Vitória ( T+I) Duque de Caxias ( T,T+I), Itaperuna (T,T+I), Niterói ( T,T+I), Nova Iguaçu ( I,T+I) and São João de Meriti ( I,T,T+I). São Paulo ( T,T+I), São Vicente (T,T+I), Sorocaba ( T,T+I), Várzea Paulista ( I,T+I), Votorantim ( I,T+I), Santana de Parnaíba ( I,T,T+I), Santos ( I,T,T+I), São Bernardo do Campo ( T,T+I), São Caetano do Sul (T+I), Arujá ( T,T+I), Bertioga (T,T+I), Botucatu ( T+I), Caçapava ( T+I), São João da Boa Vista ( I,T+I), São José do Rio Preto ( T,T+I), Campinas ( T,T+I), Cerquilho ( T+I), Diadema ( T,T+I), Embu-Guaçu ( T,T+I), São Lourenço da Serra (T,T+I), Franca ( T,T+I), Franco da Rocha ( T+I), Guarujá ( T,T+I), Ibaté ( I,T+I), Itaquaquecetuba (T,T+I), Jandira ( T+I), Jaú ( I,T+I), Jundiaí ( T,T+I), Mogi das Cruzes ( I,T,T+I), Piracicaba ( I,T,T+I), Salto ( I,T,T+I)and Santa Lucia ( I,T,T+I). Curitiba ( I,T+I) and Pinhais ( T+I) Rio Sul ( T+I), Schroeder ( I,T+I), Timbó ( T+I), Biguaçu (T+I), Blumenau ( T,T+I), Botuvará ( T,T+I), Campos Novos ( T,T+I), Cordilheira Alta ( I,T+I), Cunhataí (T,T+I), Florianópolis ( T+I), Gaspar ( I,T+I), Jaraguá do Sul ( T+I), Mafra ( I,T,T+I) and Nova Trento ( T+I), Piratuba ( I,T+I). Santa Cruz do Sul ( T+I), Santa Maria ( I,T+I), Vianão ( I,T+I), Alvorada ( I,T+I), Bento Gonçalves ( I, T+I), Casca ( I,T+I), Caxias do Sul ( I,T,T+I), Dois Irmãos ( I,T+I), Esteio ( T+I), Farroupilha ( I,T+I), Fazenda Vilanova ( T+I), Gramado ( T+I), Lagoa Vermelha (T,T+I), Lajeado ( I,T+I), Novo Hamburgo ( T,T+I), Porto Alegre ( I,T,T+I), Rio Grande (T+I), Rio Pardo ( I,T+I) and Roca Sales ( I,T+I). Mato Grosso do Sul Goiânia ( T,T+I) and Rio Quente ( T,T+I) Goiás Note: Bold Letter in Efficient Municipalities is the capital of State Table 4: Preliminary tests for spatial presence Unconditional Spatial Dependence Weight matrix - rook Variables SI p-value SP p-value SI3 p-value SP3 p-value SI2 p-value SP2 p-value Sim p-value SPm p-value Ipm p-value Moran´s I statistic 25.4737 2.20E-16 55.9222 2.20E-16 32.4531 2.20E-16 57.4308 2.20E-16 30.7199 2.20E-16 40.0036 2.20E-16 29.7062 2.20E-16 55.8353 2.20E-16 43.3889 2.20E-16 (Intercept) p-value right p-value left p-value ISSinform p-value servint p-value exp p-value transf p-value old p-value urb p-value density p-value eletr p-value compu p-value emp p-value inc p-value poverty p-value doctor p-value transport p-value spatial error p-value spatial Lag p-value LR p-value Wald p-value Llikel AIC: Adj R F-statistic: Moran´s I p-value LMerr p-value LMlag p-value Table 5 - Regression Score Efficiency for Tax Collection Dependent - Input: K , L (tax collec) Dependent - output (tax collec) Lin Reg. Spatial Lag Spatial Error Lin Reg. Spatial Lag Spatial Error 0.41960 0.31185 0.41855 0.54800 0.28098 0.56473 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 -0.00597 -0.00781 -0.00940 -0.01124 -0.01201 -0.01380 0.35501 0.21001 0.13216 0.08959 0.04362 0.01731 -0.01004 -0.01003 -0.00789 -0.02151 -0.01819 -0.01007 0.12953 0.11725 0.21978 0.00155 0.00289 0.09206 0.01182 0.01311 0.01328 0.04757 0.03639 0.02767 0.06053 0.03092 0.03131 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.01805 0.01754 0.01626 0.01614 0.01978 0.01999 0.00279 0.00260 0.00526 0.00910 0.00038 0.00022 -0.00016 -0.00015 -0.00015 -0.00005 -0.00006 -0.00006 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00613 0.00022 0.00198 -0.00003 -0.00003 -0.00003 -0.00003 -0.00003 -0.00003 0.10294 0.08967 0.07677 0.05192 0.07381 0.02514 -0.00078 -0.00077 -0.00079 -0.00496 -0.00419 -0.00290 0.22799 0.23499 0.27046 0.00000 0.00000 0.00005 0.00015 0.00025 -0.00031 0.00045 0.00058 0.27069 0.10859 0.05890 0.00239 0.00051 0.00003 0.00002 0.00003 0.00001 0.00000 0.00001 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.03607 0.82578 0.22700 0.00149 0.00097 0.00127 0.00000 0.00028 0.00029 0.01777 0.01426 0.01705 0.02788 0.01819 0.02037 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 -0.02495 -0.01364 -0.12928 0.53871 0.70921 0.00178 -0.00021 -0.00017 -0.00030 -0.00022 -0.00013 -0.00013 0.00534 0.02095 0.00030 0.00717 0.06919 0.09408 -0.00106 -0.00079 -0.00124 -0.00486 -0.00247 -0.00455 0.00041 0.00806 0.00032 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.01534 0.02385 0.01861 -0.01254 0.00930 -0.00529 0.00876 0.00003 0.00118 0.03631 0.08857 0.32714 -0.00005 -0.00004 -0.00005 -0.00007 -0.00004 -0.00007 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.34709 0.57974 0.00000 0.00000 0.28795 0.44298 0.00000 0.00000 176.67000 178.65000 564.20000 602.35000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 181.10000 196.73000 643.71000 870.79000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 1810.36300 1811.35400 1933.18100 1952.25500 -3586.70000 -3588.70000 -3826.40000 -3864.50000 0.39110 0.60570 165.70000 302.20000 14.65210 27.11460 0.00000 0.00000 208.86330 718.25780 0.00000 0.00000 210.8522, 667.19430 0.00000 0.00000 (Intercept) p-value right p-value left p-value ISSinform p-value servint p-value exp p-value transf p-value old p-value urb p-value density p-value eletr p-value compu p-value emp p-value inc p-value poverty p-value doctor p-value transport p-value spatial error p-value spatial Lag p-value LR p-value Wald p-value Llikel AIC: Adj. R F-statistic: Moran´s I p-value LMerr p-value LMlag p-value Table 6 - Regression Score Efficiency for Informal Sector Size Dependent - Input: K , L (inf. ) Dependent output (inf. ) Lin. Reg. Spatial Lag Spatial Error Lin. Reg. Spatial Lag Spatial Error 0.38740 0.24107 0.35596 0.05108 -0.00995 0.05400 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.18507 0.78685 0.19931 -0.00519 -0.00734 -0.00966 0.00129 -0.00043 -0.00275 0.42017 0.23358 0.11951 0.81313 0.93444 0.59742 0.00195 -0.00003 0.00115 0.01541 0.01352 0.01465 0.76749 0.99668 0.85720 0.00583 0.01078 0.00637 0.01038 0.01123 0.01347 0.00336 0.00263 0.00473 0.11583 0.06176 0.02811 0.52693 0.60265 0.35881 0.01983 0.01866 0.01738 0.01604 0.01502 0.01308 0.00100 0.00119 0.00267 0.00161 0.00186 0.00710 0.00002 0.00001 0.00001 0.00013 0.00010 0.00011 0.27359 0.62363 0.68304 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 -0.00013 -0.00012 -0.00012 -0.00010 -0.00008 -0.00008 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00176 0.00121 0.00076 0.00157 0.00115 0.00089 0.00908 0.06172 0.29065 0.00583 0.03366 0.14312 0.00075 0.00069 0.00065 0.00084 0.00069 0.00058 0.00000 0.00001 0.00010 0.00000 0.00000 0.00005 0.00004 0.00003 0.00003 0.00006 0.00004 0.00005 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 -0.00078 -0.00055 -0.00045 -0.00121 -0.00086 -0.00080 0.00731 0.04788 0.18039 0.00000 0.00021 0.00511 0.01529 0.01168 0.01412 0.01272 0.01000 0.01297 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 -0.12590 -0.06723 -0.09098 -0.05865 -0.02540 -0.04309 0.00145 0.07649 0.02975 0.07899 0.42384 0.22357 0.00008 0.00010 0.00007 0.00034 0.00028 0.00026 0.31020 0.17689 0.42927 0.00000 0.00001 0.00022 0.00038 0.00064 0.00027 0.00081 0.00112 0.00045 0.29713 0.06399 0.51004 0.00808 0.00012 0.19466 0.00724 0.01934 0.01179 0.00253 0.01763 0.00890 0.21423 0.00059 0.03881 0.60727 0.00021 0.06355 -0.00006 -0.00004 -0.00006 -0.00004 -0.00003 -0.00004 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00002 0.00001 0.35644 0.38337 0.00000 0.00000 0.30621 0.32843 0.00000 0.00000 217.46000 183.05000 262.37000 210.11000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 217.39000 210.40000 265.52000 253.87000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 1850.01300 1832.81200 2432.81500 2406.68800 -3662.00000 -3627.60000 -4827.60000 -4775.40000 0.41970 0.47780 142.80000 191.60000 14.61770 15.49310 0.00000 0.00000 206.37460 232.23870 0.00000 0.00000 266.52700 316.65520 0.00000 0.00000 (Intercept) p-value right p-value left p-value ISSinform p-value servint p-value exp p-value transf p-value old p-value urb p-value density p-value eletr p-value compu p-value emp p-value inc p-value poverty p-value doctor p-value transport p-value spatial error p-value spatial Lag p-value LR p-value Wald p-value Llikel AIC: Adj. R F-statistic: Moran´s p-value LMerr p-value LMlag p-value Table 7 - Regression Score Efficiency - Average Dependent - Avg. score input Dependent - Avg score output Dependent - total score average Lin. Reg. Spatial Lag Spatial Error Linear Reg. Spatial Lag Spatial Error Lin. Reg. Spatial Lag Spatial Error 0.40550 0.27674 0.39385 0.38520 0.20402 0.39545 0.39540 0.24914 0.39092 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 -0.00535 -0.00737 -0.00945 -0.00705 -0.00823 -0.01048 -0.00620 -0.00782 -0.01014 0.38692 0.21674 0.11540 0.16902 0.08067 0.02373 0.21180 0.09711 0.03102 -0.00477 -0.00553 -0.00378 -0.00894 -0.00767 -0.00201 -0.00685 -0.00677 -0.00337 0.45197 0.36589 0.54123 0.08923 0.11228 0.67345 0.17850 0.16128 0.48637 0.01107 0.01225 0.01372 0.03211 0.02506 0.02060 0.02159 0.01940 0.01858 0.06651 0.03525 0.02064 0.00000 0.00000 0.00001 0.00001 0.00002 0.00006 0.02140 0.02043 0.01912 0.01695 0.01843 0.01753 0.01917 0.01923 0.01803 0.00021 0.00024 0.00064 0.00040 0.00003 0.00005 0.00004 0.00001 0.00004 -0.00005 -0.00005 -0.00005 0.00003 0.00001 0.00002 -0.00001 -0.00002 -0.00002 0.00307 0.00176 0.00370 0.04113 0.46386 0.21867 0.42930 0.13962 0.25924 -0.00009 -0.00008 -0.00008 -0.00006 -0.00005 -0.00006 -0.00008 -0.00007 -0.00007 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00041 0.00019 -0.00005 -0.00255 -0.00233 -0.00170 -0.00107 -0.00111 -0.00104 0.52258 0.76503 0.94220 0.00000 0.00000 0.00240 0.04050 0.02493 0.06035 0.00046 0.00053 0.00053 0.00013 0.00049 0.00049 0.00029 0.00048 0.00047 0.00252 0.00035 0.00101 0.32181 0.00003 0.00020 0.01670 0.00004 0.00026 0.00003 0.00002 0.00003 0.00003 0.00001 0.00002 0.00003 0.00002 0.00002 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00031 0.00002 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 -0.00068 -0.00052 -0.00045 0.00048 0.00034 0.00057 -0.00010 -0.00006 0.00009 0.01418 0.05368 0.15348 0.03723 0.10663 0.03655 0.65110 0.76148 0.72490 0.01813 0.01455 0.01721 0.02305 0.01639 0.01876 0.02059 0.01587 0.01835 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 -0.03818 -0.00470 -0.03435 -0.04356 -0.02177 -0.09105 -0.04087 -0.01313 -0.05578 0.31408 0.89807 0.39249 0.16593 0.45217 0.00523 0.17970 0.65048 0.08315 -0.00002 0.00000 -0.00007 -0.00001 0.00001 0.00000 -0.00001 0.00000 -0.00004 0.83725 0.98342 0.38895 0.87696 0.89949 0.98994 0.83540 0.94612 0.51990 -0.00028 0.00003 -0.00046 -0.00293 -0.00141 -0.00303 -0.00160 -0.00081 -0.00178 0.41340 0.92473 0.23423 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00258 0.00000 0.00800 0.01910 0.01226 -0.00907 0.01013 -0.00164 -0.00054 0.01353 0.00493 0.15299 0.00045 0.02596 0.05062 0.01980 0.70296 0.90510 0.00180 0.25538 -0.00006 -0.00004 -0.00006 -0.00006 -0.00004 -0.00006 -0.00006 -0.00004 -0.00006 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.32686 0.52219 0.41500 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.27628 0.38409 0.31182 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 177.38000 151.87000 455.76000 468.65000 274.34000 263.87000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 178.11000 169.43000 492.86000 613.99000 283.49000 313.64000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 1965.23900 1952.48400 2730.16300 2736.60700 2745.27400 2740.03600 -3892.50000 -3867.00000 -5422.30000 -5435.20000 -5452.50000 -5442.10000 0.45700 0.65530 0.60020 176.40000 397.10000 313.80000 13.33690 24.01020 17.74260 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 171.44820 562.37740 305.47400 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 211.94650 531.47020 322.55320 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000