ESTUDOS E PESQUISAS Nº 284 The Mexican Economy in the Context of the World Economic Crisis Carlos Elizondo Mayer-Serra* XXI Fórum Nacional - Na Crise Global, o Novo Papel Mundial dos BRICs (BRIMCs?) e as Oportunidades do Brasil (Crise como Oportunidade, Através do Plano de Ação) 18 a 21 de maio de 2009 * CIDE. Versão Preliminar – Texto sujeito à revisões pelo(s) autor(es). Copyright © 2009 - INAE - Instituto Nacional de Altos Estudos. Todos os direitos reservados. Permitida a cópia desde que citada a fonte. All rights reserved. Copy permitted since source cited. INAE - Instituto Nacional de Altos Estudos - Rua Sete de Setembro, 71 - 8º andar - Rio de Janeiro - 20050-005 - Tel.: (21) 2507-7212 Fax: (21) 2232-1667 - E-mail: [email protected] - web: http://forumnacional.org.br “¿BRICs without M? On the political economy of Mexican growth” 1 Carlos Elizondo Mayer-Serra2 Introduction From 1953 to 1970 Mexico enjoyed what was then called the Mexican economic miracle, or stabilizing development. From 1953 to 1970 the average annual GDP rate of growth was 6.6 percent with an average inflation of 4.13 percent.3 The country was so successful in creating an image of a society moving towards the level of well being of developed societies, that Mexico City was granted the responsibility of hosting the Olympic games in 1968, first time ever in a developing country. This was only 4 years after Tokio´s Olympics, and 40 years before the 2008 Beijing Olympic Games. The Mexican political and economic strategy was seen as a sort of model of how to manage a complex and backwards society, without real democracy, but within certain liberties. It also avoided the military coups that plagued the rest of the region in the sixties and seventies. The economic model combined markets and private property, with a strong state, both in terms of its regulatory capacity and its direct control of strategic areas of the economy. The Mexican miracle proved, however, to be unsustainable. In 1976 first, when newly discovered oil allowed the country to postpone reforms, and then more dramatically in 1982, the country entered into a period of devaluation, inflation, and low growth. Even though the economy was finally stabilized after 1995 and a new model of development was implemented, Mexico has been incapable of achieving high growth. Mexico has the size to be one of the BRICs. In 2007 it had a population of 105.3 millions and a GDP of US $1,022.8 bn. In the same year Brazil had a population of 191.6 millions and a GDP of US $1,313.4 bn.4 Mexico exports more than all Latin America together and has a privileged geographic position. It is one of the leading exporters in world merchandise trade. In 2007 its exports had a total value of US $272 bn. Brazil’s exports were US $160 bn.5 In several interviews, Jim O’Neill, who invented the acronym BRICs has argued that Mexico should probably be included within the BRICs.6 However, in order to fulfill its potential Mexico needs to grow much more. In order to achieve that growth some key reforms are needed. This paper will first say a few words on the political economy of growth. In the second section it will describe Mexico´s growth performance, providing some comparison with other relevant countries. It starts with a long perspective, but then focus on the current moment. In the third section it will analyze why Mexico is stuck in a low growth equilibrium. Finally, this paper will address the reasons behind this mediocre performance and the likely strategies to confront the obstacles of doing the reforms that would allow the country to grow faster and therefore become one of the BRICS. On growth Institutions are crucial in understanding the political and economic development of societies.7 However, institutions are not exogenous. They are the consequence of the political equilibriums of the past. Moreover, institutions are not only the formal rules, but the informal ones that derive from history and culture, and from the capacity certain actors have to shape in its favor existing institutions. Therefore a mere change of institutions modeled on a successful country in terms of economic and political development will not transform the country that import those institutions. Institutions promote certain behaviors and hinder others; they impose restrictions, diminish uncertainty, and channel conflict. They are never neutral. They favor certain actors and behaviors and impose costs to others. They cannot be neutral because they are the result of power struggles that have well defined objectives. They can be suboptimal in terms of promoting growth, but institutions that hinder growth are difficult to change because any reform will affect powerful actors that profit from the institutions they helped shaping. Even when certain institutions are obviously hindering development, there is no agreement with respect to the optimal reform needed to foster growth or promote democracy. Reforms that might work in a certain country and world conditions, might not work in a different country or in another world context. However, some of the institutions that do not work are obvious, such as having state own firms that lose money, unregulated monopolies that extract rents from consumers, arbitrary expropriation, and extended criminal activity Economic neoclassical models suggest that the level of well being of countries that trade should converge. The poorer countries have more space to grow; they have lower wages and can import technology and capital from richer countries. However, even in economies that are open, they can end being stalled in low growth equilibrium. Institutions that protect inefficient behavior can survive because those that gain from them are powerful. This is even more likely to happen in very unequal societies, as gainers of current distribution of power have a lot of comparative resources to defend their position. Paradoxically, however, a very unequal society can assemble a large group of excluded demanding a better distribution of social good, and if they pose a real threat, elites can opt to yield something, in order to defend the bulk of their privileges. The phantom of a revolution, for example, can be a very powerful incentive for a reform that shares privileges.8 However, there is no assured outcome. Many times elites do not agree on how to share privileges. Nor it is evident that without that agreement the necessary outcome is some sort of revolution that will destroy by force the status quo. In an unequal society, those with resources have a lot of organizational and political resources to defend their position. Even in a democracy, although in principle this regime should empower majorities, it is not automatic that privileges will be eroded. The institutions of democracy can also be a safe harbor for some of the privileged, precisely because they have a lot of resources. The Mexican Economy in Perspective From a long term perspective, growth in Mexico has been mediocre compared with other countries. (See graph 1). It is worth underscoring, however, that this is not an exclusive Mexican problem. There are even less successful cases. China, perceived correctly today as a miracle, performed worst than Mexico in the past two centuries. Argentina and Chile also performed poorly. However, now Chile and China are clearly converging toward the levels of per capita income of the US. Argentina continues its secular decline, while Mexico is stagnated. Brazil is a very similar case to Mexico, although recently it has performed much better.9 We expect economies to grow. If other societies have done it, why should not all be capable of increasing their productivity and well being? However, moving toward high growth equilibrium is not easy, there are many restrictions. That explains of course why only a few countries in the history of the world have managed to do it.10 It is worth having in mind that graph number 1 compares the per capita GDP with the one of the US, which is a mobile target. The per capita GDP of the United States had an average annual growth between 1820-70 of 1.34%; from 1870-1913 of 1.82%; from 1913-50 of 1.61%; from 1950-73 of 2.45%; and from 1973-2001 of 1.86%.11 This has been a quite stable and remarkable performance. In order to grow, countries have to solve a variety of problems. The first one is of course learning to govern itself. Mexico was a relatively rich country at the beginning of its Independence. However, the problems to pacify the country after the independence necessarily had to affect our ability to grow. The independence war affected the principal economic activity of the colony, the mining industry. It also destroyed the tax collection system of the colony.12 After this war ended, a new independent state was born, but it was too unstable. This is partially explained by the low tax collection that Mexico had during that period. Without a certain degree of peace and stability there is no stable growth. The same happened during the more destructive years of the Mexican revolution. Mexico has had two periods with higher GDP per capita growth than the United States, therefore converging with the level of income of that country. These two periods were from 1855 to 1910 with the pacification of the country, the institutional development and the infrastructure of the Porfiriato, and from 1950 to 1981 with the institutionalization of the revolution and a process of development that protected the Mexican economy from imports. These two periods of high growth, however, did not turned out well, the first one ended with the revolution and its consequences, the second with a long economic crisis form which we have not fully recovered. Graph 1. Comparison of the GDP per capita between China and Latin America compared to the United States (1850-2006; International Dollars, 1990) 100% 90% 80% 70% China 60% Brazil 50% Mexico 40% Chile 30% Argentina 20% 10% 0% 1850 1870 1890 1900 1910 1917 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2006 Source: Constructed by the author with information from Angus Maddisson, Statistics on World Population, GDP and Per Capita GDP, 1-2006 AD If comparing the GDP per capita of developing countries with that of the United States is aiming to high, ¿how do Mexico compares with other developing economies? With information from the Growth Report (not comparable with the ones we used from Maddison) we can see that Mexico is at the middle of the table, even in the unproductive period of 1980 to 2006.13 In contrast to other Latin America countries, Chile stands out in this period. Brazil and Mexico have a very similar trajectory. Table 1. Growth in Developing Countries* GDP Growth Rate 1960-2006 1980-2006 China Brazil India Mexico Russian Federation Argentina Turkey Indonesia Chile Peru Real GDP 2006 2092 765 703 666 373 340 261 219 96 71 Share in total 25.4 9.3 8.5 8.1 4.5 4.1 3.2 2.7 1.2 0.9 Real Per capita 9.8 2.2 6 2.6 -0.4 1.8 4.4 5.2 4.9 2.3 8.6 0.5 4.1 0.9 -0.2 0.5 2.5 3.6 3.3 0.4 Real Per capita 7.7 4.4 4.9 4.3 2.5 4.3 5.5 4.3 3.2 6.1 2.3 2.8 2 1.1 2.2 3.6 2.5 0.9 Rank 1960 5 2 4 3 1 8 12 10 Real GDP1960 70 105 77 94 108 18 14 16 * Selected countries Source: The Growth Report. Strategies for Sustained Growth and Inclusive Development. Statistical Appendix. On the lost miracle and its implications The Mexican miracle started having problems in the seventies but finally collapsed with the 1982 economic crisis. This crisis was particularly surprising and harsh because it came after the country had become a large oil exporter. The dilemma Mexico had with the newly discovered oil wealth was how to “manage abundance”, in the infamous words of President López Portillo. His remarks were not really understood. He was not bragging about being rich, but trying to address the risks implied with the recently discovered gold pot. The problem with oil is that you start having social pressures to use not only the present income, but the future one. The expectations of future resources make creditors very generous, so you are left with even more resources than the stream derived from oil exports. It is easy to plan no to use these new arrived resources, but in a poor and unequal country it is difficult to contain expenditure pressure. If oil prices follow the expected price trajectory the strategy might work, but when you face at the same time a decrease in the price of oil, and a steep increase in interest rates, the whole strategy becomes very vulnerable. Although oil made it possible to postpone difficult decisions that first surfaced in the 1976 crisis, the 1982 crisis was much more severe because of the way oil had hidden the structural problems that resulted from a system based on commercial protection that permitted accelerated industrialization, but that lead to an inefficient economy. The low quality of Mexican goods and the increasing demand of imported inputs resulted in a chronicle need of hard currency. Politically, the so called Mexican miracle was based on the discretionary distribution of rewards and punishments. This gave the system stability. Even though it was an authoritarian system where power was controlled from above, it respected all formalities, including regular elections, thus claiming to be a democracy in a subcontinent of military coups. However, this political strategy was increasingly costly to the public purse. The need of hard currency and of public resources was financed through public external debt, but when interest rates went up in the late 1970’s and the price of oil started to go down in mid 1982, the system collapsed. Table 2. Foreign Debt of the Mexican Public Sector: 1970-1982 (Millions of dollars) Year 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 Total 3,762 4,564 5,064 1,071 9,975 14,449 19,600 22,912 26,264 29,737 33,813 32,961 64,100 Annual Increase 782 802 500 2,007 9,904 4,474 5,151 3,312 3,352 3,493 4,056 19,148 11,139 Source: Rosario Green, "El Arranque," in La deuda externa de México: 1973-1987 de la abundancia a la escasez de créditos, México: Nueva Imagen, 1988: 47. The most evident sign of this collapse was the contraction of the economy and rise in the price level. The economy went from a growth of 8.8 percent in 1981 to -0.6 percent in 1982, and in 1983 it dropped to -4.2 percent.14 Inflation went from 32.58 percent15 in 1977 to 27.93% in 1981, 57.49 percent in 1982 to 125.43 percent in 1988. It was till 1989 that the economy started to stabilize when the inflation reached 20.32 percent and 26.54 percent in 1990.16 Graph 2. CPI General Index (Annual) 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 Source: Constructed by the author with information from Banco de México. 1990 1989 1988 1987 1986 1985 1984 1983 1982 1981 1980 1979 1978 1977 1976 1975 1974 1973 1972 1971 1970 0 As the crisis could not be solved just by contracting the economy, the government decided in 1985 to open the economy and privatize a great number of state owned firms. Although the immediate objective was dealing with the economic crisis, the ultimate aim of these reforms was political. The group in power was facing an economy in crisis that went beyond the financial bankruptcy of 1982 and threatened their chances of remaining in power, as growth had been one of the reasons that allowed the government to simulate elections. What was at stake was the survival of the government and the group that controlled it, and this group was already facing serious doubts about its legitimacy as a result of successive devaluations, inflation and the lack of growth.17 Moreover, the government’s relationship with investors had been seriously damaged following the nationalization of the banks.18 Even though the reform process was intense and painful and inflation was stabilized, although after a new crisis in 1994, the government was unable to boost the economy to the rates of growth expected. Productivity and growth rates in per capita income have remained low: from 1987 to 2004, growth rates in GDP per hour worked fluctuated between 0.3 and 0.9 percent (table 3). Table 3. Growth Rates in Per Capita Income and productivity (1987-2004) GDP per capita Ireland Spain Estonia Mexico India China 1987-1995 5.1 2.5 0.4 3.9 5.7 1995-2004 6.6 3.2 6.6 2.2 4.5 6.6 GDP per hour worked (productivity) 2000-2004 4 2.6 7 -0.5 5.2 7.7 1987-1995 4 2.1 0.6 3.7 4.7 1995-2004 4.7 0 7.1 0.3 3.9 6.1 2000-2004 3.5 0.2 6.6 0.9 3.1 6.8 Source: Banque de France, Productivity, Competitivity and Globalization, Paris: Banque de France, EUROSYSTÈME, November 2005. If we compare Mexico´s growth in the last years to key developing countries it is evident we are being left behind, making it difficult to claim being one of the BRICS. Throughout the last years Brazil had a far better performance than Mexico’s (Table 4).19 Table 4. Real GDP (Annual percent change) Brazil China India Mexico Russian Fede 2007 5.7 13 9.3 3.3 8.1 2008 5.1 9 7.3 1.3 5.6 2009 est. –1.3 6.5 4.5 –3.7 –6.0 2010 est. 2.2 7.5 5.6 1 0.5 Source: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook Database, April 2009. To the low level of growth of these past years we have to add the complexities derived from the world crisis and more recently, the influenza which affected severely the Mexican economy. During the first trimester of 2009 the real GDP of Mexico dropped -8.2 percent,20 The collapse was deeper than what the IMF was forecasting in April. The expected growth for this year for Mexico is of -5.5 percent21 and for the next one is of 2 percent,22 but some economists have even more negative forecasts. This crisis has severely affected the Mexican economy, but Mexico is not as vulnerable as it was in the 1994 or 1988 crisis (see Graph 3), Mexico’s current account deficit as a percent of the GDP in 2008 was of -1.67 percent, the predicted one for 2009 is -1.92 percent. If we exclude oil from the current account the deficit is still not comparable with past crisis. Graph 3. Current Account Deficit as a % of the GDP Source: Raúl Feliz, “Análisis Económico,” CIDE. There have been some inflationary pressures, the inflation rate in December of 2008 was of 6.53 percent; the highest Mexico has had in the last couple of years. However, the rate of inflation decreased during the first trimester of 2009 and it is expected to remain within the Central Bank’s (Banxico) superior limit in June of 2010 (see Graph 4). Graph 4. Inflation Source: Raúl Feliz, “Análisis Económico,” CIDE. Just as other emerging economies, it has accumulated high international reserves (Graph 5) compared to those in December of 1994 (US $5bn)23, and low public debt (Graph 6). For the first time ever in a crisis, the Mexican government has been able to take counter cyclical measures to counteract the crisis. For example, it has approved a program for employment and work benefits (US $1.5 bn), one for households (US $7bn), business and industry (US $11bn) and a new fund for infrastructure investment (US $36 bn). These packages amount to 2.8 percent of GDP,24 although it was yet been fully spent. Graph 5: International Reserves (Log) Billions of U.S. dollars 10000 1000 100 10 2001 2002 Brazil 2003 China 2004 2005 India 2006 Mexico 2007 2008 2009p 2010p Russian Federation Source: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook Database, April 2009. Graph 6. Mexico’s Public Sector Debt: 1990-2010 Source: Raúl Feliz, “Análisis Económico,” CIDE. Employment has been severely affected by the crisis. In Mexico only in the first trimester of 2009 more than 2 million works were lost.25 The loss is expected to be greater in the following months (Graph 7), affecting the capacity to use internal demand as a substitute for the collapse of external demand. Graph 7. Income and Employment Growth Source: Raúl Feliz, “Análisis Económico,” CIDE. The severity of the current crisis is basically the result of the integration with the US economy, the epicenter of this world crisis. Just as we have seen with other major exporters, like Germany of Japan their problems have been more severe than less open economies. Although the current crisis comes abroad, the low growth of the years previous to the crisis is domestic, basically explained by the many reforms the country still needs.26 The most evident ones are opening the energy sector, liberalizing labor markets, strengthening the capacity to regulate dominant players in key sectors such as telecommunications, a stronger and less distortive tax structure and a stronger rule of law. An urgent reform is fiscal reform. As Graph 9 shows the price of oil has dropped drastically. If in 2009 is not yet a serious problem it is because the Mexican government bought insurances in case that the crude oil price per barrel went below $70 dollars. Next year the pressure will be unavoidable, if prices do not recuperate to its levels of 2008, the most likely scenario. Tax recollection is low compared to other countries. Oil income has compensated this weak tax capacity, (Graph 8) helped by high oil prices (Graph 9). In the first four months of 2009 (Graph 8.1) oil income of the government has gone down, even more than tax income, thus decreasing its percentage, but at the expense of weaker public finances. Graph 8.Budgetary Income of the Public Sector, Mexico. 2000-2008. (% of total) 80% 70% 67% 70% 70% 67% 64% 65% 63% 62% 63% 60% 50% 40% 36% 33% 37% 38% 35% 37% 33% 30% 30% 30% 20% 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Oil Incomes Non Oil Incomes Graph 8.1 Budgetary Income of the Public Sector, Mexico. January – April, 2006-2009. (% of total) 80% 73% 70% 66% 68% 67% 60% 50% 40% 34% 32% 33% 30% 27% 20% 2006 2007 Oil Income 2008 2009 Non Oil Income Source: “Estadísticas oportunas de finanzas públicas,” Secretaría de Hacienda y Crédito Público. But the problem is more than just a fiscal one. The trade balance of oil and its derivatives has deteriorated recently (see Graph 10). And production is declining (Graph 11). Graph 9. Average Realized Price of Crude Oil Exports Source: Petróleos Mexicanos, “Indicadores petroleros a marzo de 2009,” www.pemex.com Graph 10. Pemex Trade Balance Source: Petróleos www.pemex.com Mexicanos, “Indicadores petroleros, marzo de 2009,” Graph 11. Mexican Oil Production by Type (thousands barrels daily) Source: Pemex, “Petroleum Statistics,” Investor Relations. Mexico is not only in need of a fiscal reform, it also needs to regulate dominant firms in key sectors, such as telecommunication. In Mexico Telmex and America Movil dominate fix and mobile markets. (See Graph 12). Both are owned by Carlos Slim, the richest man in Latin America and one of richest in the world. The telecommunication market in Mexico can be considered to be a monopoly because it has a Herfindahl-Hirschman index of concentration of 8,868 (see Graph 13). The result of this lack of options is that even though Mexico is a poor country, Mexicans pay per capita for telecommunications fees (fixed, mobile and Internet) more than in rich countries as Switzerland, United Kingdom and United States (Graph 14). Graph 12. Cellular Mobile Competition in the OECD, 2005 Mobile operator market share according to number of subscribers (%) 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Operator 1 Operator 2 Operator 3 Operator 4 Operator 5 Source: OECD, Communications Outlook 2007, París: OECD. Otro Graph 13. Supply Concentration in Telephony (at end 2005) Herfindahl-Hirschman Index, by segment Note: The Herfindahl-Hirschman concentration index is constructed as the sum of market shares in each segment expressed in percentages: 0 corresponds to an atomistic market, 10 000 to a monopoly. Source: OCDE, “Latin American Economic Outlook 2008” Graph 14. Monthly household expenditure on communications in selected OECD countries 280 260 240 220 200 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 Monthly expenditures on communications (USD) Internet Mobile Fixed Total Source: OECD, Communications Outlook 2007, París: OECD. On the political economy of pending reforms27 Many reforms were not done or were limited, but there were errors in the implementation of those reforms that actually took place. The most visible one was the crisis of 1994. This broke with the premises of economic reform: that liberalization and privatization would provide stability and growth. This failure made the modernizing reforms not any longer popular. In October 1994, at the end of President Salinas’s six-year term, 52.2 percent of those interviewed for a survey were in favor of privatization, 38.2 percent were against it, and the remaining 9.6 percent were indifferent. After the 1994 crisis, when the peso was devalued from $3.37 peso/dollar (annual average 1994) to $6.17 peso/dollar (annual average 1995), the economy contracted -4.7 percent (in 1994 the GDP growth rate was of 3.5%)28 and inflation jumped to 34.77 percent in 1995 (in 1994 it was of 6.97 percent).29 Only one year into Ernesto Zedillo’s government, the perception of privatization had changed. In April 1995, the percentage of those in favor of privatization had fallen below 28.1 percent (that is, slightly more than half the earlier level), 35.7 percent were against it and 36.2 were indifferent. The legislators confronting the current president, Felipe Calderón, in his attempts at fiscal, energy, and labor reform, now that the three most visible reforms, fiscal, labour and energy, are not popular. Public opinion perceives these reforms not as favorable to the interests of the majority, but as part of a sinister plan to erode its interests. According to the national poll Serie Nacional Parametría done by the polling company Parametría, 73 percent of those surveyed believe that the government should control the economy and 55 percent are opposed to any increase in private capital in the oil and electricity industries. By the same token, a 2007 Mitofsky poll shows that more than half the population is opposed to private investment in energy. The lost of legitimacy of economic reforms derived from these crisis, plus the power of potentially affected groups in case of further reforms, and the distribution of votes, have led to no major economic reforms in the last 15 years. Not only are pending reforms not popular. Transition came to Mexico in a context where the president’s party no longer had an overall majority in either of the two chambers. Divided governments have made it difficult for the executive branch to assume the short-term cost of certain legal reforms and then to enjoy the medium- to long-term potential benefits, although it is worth having in mind that all the reforms still needed were not passed during the years of unified government, and thus the causality of divided government having less capacity for action is not clear.30 Graph 14. Divided Government Chamber of Deputies Source: CIDAC (http://www.cidac.org) and Cámara de Diputados (http://www.diputados.gob.mx) Senate Source: Alonso Lujambio, El Poder compartido. Un ensayo sobre la democratización mexicana, México, Océano, 2000, p.75. and Cámara de Senadores (www.senado.gob.mx) The opposition is currently in the hands of two parties who are heirs to the ideological principles, revolutionary nationalism, and political practices of the PRI governments. In the case of the PRD, rejection of the most important outstanding reforms is almost automatic, because the PRD arose out of opposition to Salinas’s reform agenda. In the case of the PRI, the relationship is more ambiguous; however, after the 1994 crisis, a lot of power was lost by the modernizing stream that had come from the high bureaucracy controlling the party that was not really a product of PRI traditional cadres, closer to the rank and file of the party. This dispersion of power has helped those against reforms to avoid changes. The main actors benefiting from this lack of reforms and making reforms difficult are big businesses in sectors where there is limited competition and the trade unions of the public sector. These two groups are two sides of the same problem: sectors with scant competition that extract rents from the consumer or from the taxpayer. In the first case, business people do this through relatively high prices and low personal taxes. Significantly for a country with such marked inequality, the idea of an inheritance tax is not even up for consideration, something that reflects the power of those who stand to be affected. Quite apart from whether an inheritance tax is a good tax (given that it brings in little and can be evaded), it is surprising that the idea is not part of the debate, because the proportion of wealth in the hands of billionaires is greater in Mexico than in many other countries, including some of the countries in the region with the greatest inequality, and because most of Mexico’s billionaires inherited their wealth. Big businesses have always been able to affect government actions. For many decades, big businesses concentrated their actions on the executive branch with considerable success. This was the case from 1940 to 1970, years that were also called the alliance for profit. The governing principle was support for making money in exchange for noninterference in politics.31 In a democratic world, the playing field is much bigger. Businesses seeking to influence all players in the policy process have had to create departments to handle relationships with the government, especially Congress, and also to influence public opinion. Some business people have actively sought the presidency, as was the case with Fox. Others have played an active role in elections by contributing money and other forms of support. Given the absence of regulation on lobbying the room for action is wide open and there are cases of notable success for special interests. The unions also extract rents in the form of very good pensions, no accountability, and low productivity.32 In general, the public sector trade unions are unaffected by low product quality or losses their employers’ suffer. Even though the income public sector workers earn is miniscule compared with the salaries of owners of large businesses, and even though these workers continue to earn less than the upper-middle class, they still enjoy better working conditions and income compared to workers with similar education and are very costly to the public purse. This situation reduces the possibility of instituting more progressive and better quality social spending and saddles the economy as a whole with expensive, poor quality services. Proposing greater public spending that would narrow the inequality gap via focused transfers and better public services in education and health is difficult if one part of such spending has been captured by the trade unions and if the capacity to provide a good quality service is limited because of labor agreements that do not promote productivity. One extreme case is Luz y Fuerza del Centro, a state-owned electricity utility company. It supplies electricity to a territorially concentrated market, central Mexico, where per capita income levels are high compared with the rest of the country. The company does not sell its electricity cheaply, but is still losing a good deal of money. In 2008, transfers and subsidies to the company to avoid bankruptcy will amount to some Mex$32.5 billion, which is equivalent to 157 percent of the budget of Mexico’s largest public university.33 The inefficiencies in the public sector are manifold. Some efforts have been made to quantify the problem34, but even anecdotal evidence reveals sizable productivity problems, which are the result of a politicized corporate system that tolerates deadwood in personnel and low productivity.35 In Petróleos Mexicanos (PEMEX), for example, 11,450 workers on the payroll do absolutely nothing, because the collective contract makes it impossible to dismiss personnel whose jobs no longer exist. The cost to the company is Mex$4 billion per year. These numbers do not include excess staff in many processes that are also effectively doing nothing.36 One study of PEMEX has identified potential annual savings of Mex$17,600 million, but part of this would come only at the expense of confronting the trade union.37 Trade unions have served their members well. Their average wages are higher than in the rest of the economy. Between 1998 and 2001, that is, during the end of Zedillo’s term and the beginning of Fox’s administration, a teacher’s basic salary rose by 52.4 percent and fringe benefits rose by 9.1 percent. Indeed, since 1993, teachers’ wages have risen more in real terms than GDP.38 Even though their salaries continue to be low compared with what teachers earn in more developed countries, they are high in comparison with Mexico’s per capita GDP. In general, despite the commonly held perception, primary school teachers in the public education system earn more than those in other professions with comparable levels of qualifications.39 In addition, they have much better working conditions: more vacation days, more flexible work schedules that allow them to hold second jobs, and greater job security. No wonder that selling job placements is a profitable business. The most extreme case is that of the Sindicato Mexicano de Electricistas to which Luz y Fuerza del Centro workers belong. This is probably the most democratic and independent of the public sector workers’ unions. It has also achieved the best working conditions for its members, including retirement pensions at a level not found in any developed country.40 Because public sector firms are not subject to competition and do not live off income earned from the market, they are in a position to perpetuate inefficient union agreements that continue to be paid for out of the public purse. This is very different from what happens in the manufacturing sector, where productivity has improved dramatically, even without reform to Mexico’s burdensome Labor Law. In sectors open to competition, the trade unions are limited as to what they can demand. They understand what is at stake, and most have moderated their stance accordingly. Even a combative trade union such as that of Volkswagen of Mexico knows that the company can take its investment say to Brazil or back to Germany. The Labor Law imposes many restrictions, but the biggest problems occur in sectors that face little competition or that cannot go bankrupt because they are subsidized by the government. Given the political clout of the trade unions, withdrawing subsidies that allow the firms to survive is difficult. Even when this appears to have been achieved, a trade union can always renege on its decision. Luz y Fuerza del Centro was already in the hands of liquidators when Salinas halted the process and the government ended up absorbing the company’s liabilities. This was apparently in compensation for a close relationship that had proved useful to his candidacy when the oil workers union withdrew its support. Conclusions The challenges ahead are particularly complex, now having to confront also an unprecedented world crisis and the short term costs of the influenza. Even if the US economy were to rebound fast, which is not evident it will take place soon, the US will not have the spending capacity of the last decades for some time. Mexico will need to diversify its markets and strengthen its domestic markets. This is easy to say, but requires to make the economy more competitive. This can only be achieved by following those major reforms pending, such as energy, labor, regulatory, fiscal and educational, to mention the most conspicuous. To make thinks more difficult, the country will be facing a dual challenge as a result of the collapse of the price of oil, and the decreasing Mexican oil production. The first challenge is fiscal. In 2008 oil income was slightly under 40 percent of total government income. This year the government can cope with lower price, because it bought a hedge in case the price went below 70 dollars per barrel. But next the fiscal pressure will require a reform capable of raising at least 2 points of GDP, and not only prices will probably remain lower than in 2008, but production is declining. Moreover, the decline in GDP is also pushing tax income down. The second challenge is a more limited oil surplus. This will oblige the Mexican economy to export more, although less oil income will lead to less currency appreciation. Although oil prices might remain lower than in 2008, they are still high in comparative terms. Transport costs are likely to remain high. This should help Mexico in its capacity to export to the United States. But to confront the challenges and capture any opportunity opened by the crisis, Mexico has to pursue a series of reforms. This will not take place as long as Mexico is not prepared to confront powerful interest groups. Trade unions and big businessmen are happy with the status quo. How can Mexico build a political coalition that will break with the prevailing equilibrium that is obstructing greater growth and unduly favors those who have resources and organizational power? Democracy should serve to unite the public against the special interest groups and can propagate reforms beneficial to the majority in the medium term. This calls for strong leadership with a clear strategy for standing up to these well-organized groups and with solid information that would enable that leadership to justify its actions. It also calls for citizens ready to get involved in the public policy debate and to take a stand in defense of their own interests. In a democracy one tends to have the government one deserves. A lot can be said of strengthening our political institutions to have more responsive authorities. However, at the end, a more mobilized and informed society that punishes irresponsible politicians is the only way out. The current institutions, however, do not help. There is no immediate reelection in the legislative and it is absolutely banned for governors and president. How can people punish the elected ones? They can change the party they vote for, but it is an indirect punishment. Reforming political institutions is thus also needed. In the past Mexico proved it could organize itself to create an economic miracle. But this was achieved in a non democratic political system that was trapped in a costly net of interest groups that made the miracle unsustainable. This net of interest groups still haunts Mexico. Now in a democratic society, tough decisions that are of general interest should be easier to undertake, although this will require a more organized, well informed, and demanding society. But the example of countries like Brazil show this is possible. If Mexico were to pursue successfully the needed reforms, it would add the M to the BRICs acronym. 1 A draft of this paper was presented at: “In the Midst of a World Crisis, the New Global Role of the Brics (BRIMCs?), and Brazil’s Opportunities (Crisis as an opportunity, using the action plan),” XXI National Forum, Bndes, Río de Janeiro, May 18-21 of 2009. 2 Professor at the Political Studies Faculty of the Centro de Investigación y Docencia Económicas, Carretera México-Toluca 3655, col. Lomas de Santa Fe, C.P. 01210, México, D.F. Email: [email protected]. The author thanks Oscar Mendoza for his help. All errors are of course the author’s responsibility. 3 Pascual García Alba Iduñate and Jaime Serra Puche, “El financiamiento del desarrollo en México,” in Causas y efectos de la crisis económica en México, México: Centro de Estudios Económicos, Colegio de México, 1984: 28.. 4 . “Key Development Data & Statistics”. WTO, 2008. 5 WTO, “Table 2.B. Leading exporters and importers in world merchandise trade, 2007,” in International Trade Statistics 2008 6 See http://reflexioneslibertarias.blogspot.com/2009/04/para-su-creador-los-bric-pueden.html and http://www.esmas.com/finanzaspersonales/576088.html 7 Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson “Institutions as the Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth,” American Economic Review, 95, 546-79, 2005; Stanley L. Engerman y Kenneth L. Sokoloff “Factor Endowments, Institutions, and Differential Paths of Growth among New World Economies” NBER Working Paper, 2002; Stephen L. Parente and Edward C. Prescott “Barriers to Riches” Cambridge, MIT Press, 2000. Douglass C. North y Robert Paul Thomas, The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History, Cambridge University 1973. 8 Daron Acemoglu, “The Form of Property Rights: Oligarchic Versus Democratic Societies” NBER Working Paper 10037, 2003. El caso paradigmático de una élite que reparte beneficios para no ser rebasada es probablemente la Alemania de Bismark, véase Otto Pflanze, Bismarck and the Development of Germnay. The Period of Unification, 1815-1871, USA: Princeton University Press, 1971. 9 Such a long time series might have a problem of confidence. In this case we have used the series constructed by Maddison, probably the most accurate. 10 World Bank, The Growth Report: strategies for Sustained Growth and Inclusive Development. 11 Elaborado con base en los datos presentados en Angus Maddison, The World Economy: Historical Statistics (2003), París: OCDE. 12 Carlos Marichal, “Imperial Tax State,” en Bankruptcy of Empire: Mexican Silver and the Wars between Spain, Britain and France, Cabridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007. 13 World Bank, The Growth Report: strategies for Sustained Growth and Inclusive Development. 14 Lawrence R. Klein and Alfredo Coutiño, “The A Mexican Adjustment Scenario,” in Ensayo sobre aspectos macroeconómicos de México, Mexico City: Instituto de Investigación Económica y Social Lucas Alamán, A.C., 2000: 88. 15 Pascual García Alba Iduñate and Jaime Serra Puche, “El financiamiento del desarrollo en México,” in Causas y efectos de la crisis económica en México, México: Centro de Estudios Económicos, Colegio de México, 1984: 39. 16 Centro de Estudios de las Finanzas Públicas de la H. Cámara de Diputados, con datos del Banco, México: Inflación Anual, 1980 - 2009 (Base segunda quincena de Junio de 2002=100). 17 Miguel Angel Centeno, Democracy within Reason: Technocratic Revolution in Mexico. Pennsylvania: The Pennsylvania State University Press University Park, 1997. 18 Carlos Elizondo, La importancia de las reglas: gobierno y empresarios después de la nacionalización de la banca. Mexico City: Fondo de Cultura Económica, 2001.. 19 International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook Database, April 2009. 20 “Producto interno bruto trimestral”, in INEGI, Servicio de Información Estadística de Coyuntura (SIEC). 21 Gustavo de la Rosa e Iván Sosa, “Se acerca del desempleo al peor nivel,” en Reforma , 16 de mayo de 2009. 22 Secretaría de Hacienda y Crédito Público 23 Lawrence R. Klein and Alfredo Coutiño, “The Mexican Financial Crisis of December 1994 and Lessons to be Learned,” in Ensayo sobre aspectos macroeconómicos de México, Mexico City: Instituto de Investigación Económica y Social Lucas Alamán, A.C., 2000: 58. 24 Secretaría de Hacienda y Crédito Público 25 Inegi, Encuesta nacional de ocupación y empleo, 2009. 26 Fabrice Lehoucq, Why Is Structural Reform Stagnating in Mexico? Mexico City: Centro de Investigación y Docencia Económicas, 2006. 27 This section is a synthesis from: Carlos Elizondo, “Perverse Equilibria: Unsuitable but Durable Institutions,” in No Growth Without Equity? Inequality, Interests and Competition in Mexico, ed. Santiago Levy & Michael Walton, United States: World Bank Publications, February 26, 2009. 28 Lawrence R. Klein and Alfredo Coutiño, “The Mexican Financial Crisis of December 1994 and Lessons to be Learned,” in Ensayo sobre aspectos macroeconómicos de México, Mexico City: Instituto de Investigación Económica y Social Lucas Alamán, A.C., 2000: 61-2. 29 Centro de Estudios de las Finanzas Públicas de la H. Cámara de Diputados, con datos del Banco, México: Inflación Anual, 1980 - 2009 (Base segunda quincena de Junio de 2002=100). 30 José AntonioCheibub, Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, and Democracy. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 2007. 31 Clark W.Reynolds, The Mexican Economy, Twentieth Century: Structure and Growth. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1970. 32 See Isabel Guerrero, Luis Felipe López-Calva, and Michael Walton, “The Inequality Trap and Its Links to Low Growth in Mexico,” in No Growth Without Equity? Inequality, Interests and Competition in Mexico, ed. Santiago Levy & Michael Walton, United States: World Bank Publications, February 26, 2009. 33 “Presupuesto de Egresos de la Federación para el Ejercicio Fiscal 2008”. Secretaría de Haciendia y Crédito Público. http://www.shcp.gob.mx/. 34 Fabrice Lehoucq, Why Is Structural Reform Stagnating in Mexico? Mexico City: Centro de Investigación y Docencia Económicas, 2006. 35 World Bank. Mexico: Institutional and Governance Review. Report 37293, MX. Washington, DC: World Bank, 2006. 36 Alma Hernández, “Mantiene Pemex a ociosos.” Reforma, December 28, 2006. 37 Alma Hernández, “Detecta Pemex posibles ahorros.” Reforma, December 29, 2006, Negocios. 38 World Bank. Mexico: Institutional and Governance Review. Report 37293, MX. Washington, DC: World Bank, 2006. 39 Gladys López Acevedo, “Teachers’ Salaries and Professional Profile in Mexico,” Working Paper 3394, World Bank, Washington, DC, 2004. 40 The secretary general of the trade union is 41 years old and has belonged to the union for 22 years. According to the collective labor contract, Article 64: “Any worker can request and obtain retirement provided he has completed twenty-five years of service and is fifty-five years old, or provided that he has completed thirty years of service regardless of age. By the same token, women workers can request and obtain retirement with 100% (a hundred percent) of their basic salary, when they have completed twenty-five years of service regardless of age.” Thus in 10 years’ time, the secretary general will be able to retire on his full salary, which each year includes a Christmas bonus equivalent to 50 days’ pay (http://www.sme.org.mx/construccion_frame/UntitledFrameset-3.htm). The Mexican Economy in the Context of the World Economic Crisis Carlos Elizondo Mayer-Serra [email protected] XXI National Forum Rio de Janeiro, Brazil May 18, 2009 CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Index The Mexican Economy in Perspective The Mexican Economy and the Crisis The Immediate Reaction Challenges and opportunities Comparison of per capita GDP in China CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Porcentaje Porcentaje and Latin America with that of the United States 1820 – 2000* *International dollar (1990). Source: Maddison, Angus, The World Economy: Historical Statistics (2003), París: OCDE Comparison of per capita GDP in China CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Porcentaje Porcentaje and Latin America with that of the United States 1820 – 2000* *International dollar (1990). Source: Maddison, Angus, The World Economy: Historical Statistics (2003), París: OCDE Comparison of per capita GDP in China CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Porcentaje Porcentaje and Latin America with that of the United States 1820 – 2000* *International dollar (1990). Source: Maddison, Angus, The World Economy: Historical Statistics (2003), París: OCDE Comparison of per capita GDP in China CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Porcentaje Porcentaje and Latin America with that of the United States 1820 – 2000* *International dollar (1990). Source: Maddison, Angus, The World Economy: Historical Statistics (2003), París: OCDE CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Growth in Developing Countries GDP growth rate 1980-2006 Real GDP Share in 2006 total 1960-2006 Real Per capita Real Per cápita Rank 1960 Real GDP 1960 China 2092 25.4 9.8 8.6 7.7 6.1 5 70 Brazil 765 9.3 2.2 0.5 4.4 2.3 2 105 India 703 8.5 6 4.1 4.9 2.8 4 77 Mexico Russian Federation 666 8.1 2.6 0.9 4.3 2 3 94 373 4.5 -0.4 -0.2 - - - - Argentina 340 4.1 1.8 0.5 2.5 1.1 1 108 Turkey 261 3.2 4.4 2.5 4.3 2.2 - - Indonesia 219 2.7 5.2 3.6 5.5 3.6 8 18 Chile 96 1.2 4.9 3.3 4.3 2.5 12 14 Peru 71 0.9 2.3 0.4 3.2 0.9 10 16 Source: The Growth Report . Strategies For Sustained Growth and Inclusive Development. Statistical Appendix. * Selected Countries CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 The Last Three Years Consumer Prices 1 Real GDP Current Account Balances 2 2007 2008 2009 est. 2010 est. 2007 2008 2009 est. 2010 est. 2007 2008 2009 est. 2010 est. Brazil 5.7 5.1 –1.3 2.2 3.6 5.7 4.8 4 0.1 –1.8 –1.8 –1.8 China 13 9 6.5 7.5 4.8 5.9 0.1 0.7 11 10 10.3 9.3 India 9.3 7.3 4.5 5.6 6.4 8.3 6.3 4 –1.0 –2.8 –2.5 –2.6 Mexico Russian Federation 3.3 1.3 –3.7 1 4 5.1 4.8 3.4 –0.8 –1.4 –2.5 –2.2 8.1 5.6 –6.0 0.5 9 14.1 12.9 9.9 5.9 6.1 0.5 1.4 1 Movements in consumer prices are shown as annual averages. 2 Percent of GDP. * Source: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook Database, April 2009. CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Index The Mexican Economy in Perspective The Mexican Economy and the Crisis The Immediate Reaction Challenges and opportunities Mexico´s perspectives CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 • U.S. contraction likely to sharply curtail Mexico's growth • Mexico faces global crisis, but from far stronger position than in past • Decline in remittances and lower international oil prices • Problems agravated by the influenza CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 United States & Mexico’s Growth Annual Average EEUU México 2008 1.13% 1.38% 2009 -1.80% -3.38% 2010 1.50% 3.00% 2011 2.66% 3.36% 2012 2.66% 3.36% Predictions CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Current Account Deficit as a % of the GDP Pronósticos Predictions Public Sector Debt: 1990-2010 CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Predictions CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Income and Employment Growth Inflation CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Mexico´s Growth CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 • In 2008: 1.3%1 • Expected GDP growth for the Mexican economy in 2009: -3.8% 2 • After swine flu it could be between -4.3% to -4.6% 2 • Expected GDP growth for the Mexican economy in 2010: 2%3 1 Source: “Banco de Información Económica,” INEGI. Source: Moody’s Weekly Credit Outlook, May 4, 2009. 3 Source: SHCP 2 CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Index The Mexican Economy in Perspective The Mexican Economy and the Crisis The Immediate Reaction Challenges and opportunities What Has Been Done? CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 • Mexico’s financial authorities have taken measures to address liquidity strains in the financial markets • The financial system remains well capitalized Source: http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/survey/so/2009/car032009a.htm What Has Been Done? CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 • The flexible exchange rate has helped the economy to adjust to the global crisis http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/survey/so/2009/car032009a.htm CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Counter-Cyclical Measures Adopted by the Mexican Government • Employment and work benefits (US$1.5bn) • Flexible use of retirement funds and increased government contributions (US$1bn) • Extended time coverage of social security health care for laid-off workers (US$200m) • Budget increase of the Temporal Employment Program (US$170m) • Employment Preservation Program (US$150m) • Households (US$7bn) • Increased finance for housing acquisition and improvement (US$6.5bn) • Food Support Program (US$410m) • Gasoline price fixation and 10% cut on LP Gas prices CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Counter-Cyclical Measures Adopted by the Mexican Government • Business and Industry (US$11bn) • Increased financing by development banks (US$9bn) • Industrial electricity price cuts (US$620m) • Discount on employers’ dues for social security (US$600m) • Financing for Small and Medium enterprises (US$500m) • Income tax incentives and discounts (US$500m) • Infrastructure investment (US$36bn) • National Infrastructure Fund (US$25bn, five-year plan) • PEMEX infrastructure (US$9bn) • Finance from Development Banks (US$2bn) CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Counter-Cyclical Measures Adopted by the Mexican Government • The overall government stimulus effort for 2008 and 2009 amounts to 2.8% of GDP. • BUT, no new structural reform. CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Index The Mexican Economy in Perspective The Mexican Economy and the Crisis The Immediate Reaction Challenges and opportunities CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Is the Crisis an Opportunity? • Structural reforms needed – Energy reform CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Mexican Oil Production by Type (thousands barrels daily) * Source: Pemex, “Petroleum Statistics,” Investor Relations. CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Is the Crisis an Opportunity? • Labour reform • Regulatory reform • Tax reform Structural Reforms? • Reforming is not easy – Divided government CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Divided Government Chamber of Deputies, Mexico Source: CIDAC (http://www.cidac.org) y Cámara de Diputados ( http://www.diputados.gob.mx) Divided Government CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 Mexican Senate Source: Alonso Lujambio, El Poder compartido. Un ensayo sobre la democratización mexicana, México, Océano, 2000, p.75. y Cámara de Senadores (www.senado.gob.mx) Mediocre Growth CARLOS ELIZONDO MAYER-SERRA May 18, 2009 • Without reforms – Low growth equilibrum – Complex but achievable tax balance The example of Brazil