ISSN 1518-3548 Working Paper Series Nonlinear Mechanisms of the Exchange Rate Pass-Through: A Phillips curve model with threshold for Brazil Arnildo da Silva Correa and André Minella November, 2006 ISSN 1518-3548 CGC 00.038.166/0001-05 Working Paper Series Brasília N. 122 Nov 2006 P. 1-30 Working Paper Series Edited by Research Department (Depep) – E-mail: [email protected] Editor: Benjamin Miranda Tabak – E-mail: [email protected] Editorial Assistent: Jane Sofia Moita – E-mail: [email protected] Head of Research Department: Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo – E-mail: [email protected] The Banco Central do Brasil Working Papers are all evaluated in double blind referee process. Reproduction is permitted only if source is stated as follows: Working Paper n. 122. Authorized by Afonso Sant’Anna Bevilaqua, Deputy Governor of Economic Policy. General Control of Publications Banco Central do Brasil Secre/Surel/Dimep SBS – Quadra 3 – Bloco B – Edifício-Sede – M1 Caixa Postal 8.670 70074-900 Brasília – DF – Brazil Phones: (5561) 3414-3710 and 3414-3567 Fax: (5561) 3414-3626 E-mail: [email protected] The views expressed in this work are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Banco Central or its members. Although these Working Papers often represent preliminary work, citation of source is required when used or reproduced. As opiniões expressas neste trabalho são exclusivamente do(s) autor(es) e não refletem, necessariamente, a visão do Banco Central do Brasil. Ainda que este artigo represente trabalho preliminar, citação da fonte é requerida mesmo quando reproduzido parcialmente. Consumer Complaints and Public Enquiries Center Address: Secre/Surel/Diate Edifício-Sede – 2º subsolo SBS – Quadra 3 – Zona Central 70074-900 Brasília – DF – Brazil Fax: (5561) 3414-2553 Internet: http://www.bcb.gov.br/?english Nonlinear Mechanisms of the Exchange Rate Pass-Through: A Phillips curve model with threshold for Brazil * Arnildo da Silva Correa** André Minella** The Working Papers should not be reported as representing the views of the Banco Central do Brasil. The views expressed in the papers are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the Banco Central do Brasil. Abstract This paper investigates the presence of nonlinear mechanisms of pass-through from the exchange rate to inflation in Brazil. In particular, it estimates a Phillips curve with a threshold for the pass-through. The paper examines whether the short-run magnitude of the pass-through is affected by the business cycle, direction and magnitude of exchange rate changes, and exchange rate volatility. The results indicate that the short-run pass-through is higher when the economy is growing faster, when the exchange rate depreciates above some threshold and when exchange rate volatility is lower. These results have important implications for monetary policy and are possibly related to pricing-to-market behavior, menu costs of price adjustment and uncertainty about the degree of persistence in exchange rate movements. Keywords: Exchange Rate Pass-Through, Threshold, Inflation, Nonlinearity, Brazil JEL Classification: E31, E50, E58 * We are thankful to Fabio Araújo and Tomiê Sugahara for their participation in initial estimations, Carlos Hamilton Araújo, Ana Beatriz Galvão and Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos for suggestions, Érica Oliveira and Ibitisan Santos for assistance with data, and others colleagues at the Research Department of the Central Bank of Brazil for their contributions and comments. The views herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Central Bank of Brazil. ** Research Department, Central Bank of Brazil. E-mails: [email protected] and [email protected] 3 1. Introduction The presence of nonlinearities in the Phillips curve has relevant implications for monetary policy. The slope of the Phillips curve – measuring the response of inflation to output gap – affects directly the cost of disinflation. Schaling (2004) shows that, when the Phillips curve is convex, that is, the sensitivity of inflation to economic activity increases with the level of output, the optimal monetary policy reaction function is asymmetric. Nonlinearity may also be present in the pass-through from exchange rate changes to prices. If the pass-through, for instance, is greater when the economy is booming, we may consider that the central bank's reaction to a depreciation of the domestic currency will be stronger in this context. In fact, the investigation of the presence of nonlinear mechanisms in the Phillips curve has been an important topic in the recent literature.1 Most studies on nonlinear Phillips curves for developed economies have focused on the slope of the Phillips curve and the exchange rate pass-through. In the first case, Laxton, Rose and Tambakis (1999) and Bean (2000) find evidence that the Phillips curve is convex, while Stiglitz (1997) and Eisner (1997) claim that the Phillips curve is concave.2 The literature on exchange rate pass-through, in turn, reports several sources of nonlinearity, indicating that the degree of pass-through can be related to some macroeconomic variable, including the exchange rate. Mann (1986), Goldberg (1995), Gil-Pareja (2000), Mahdavi (2002) and Olivei (2002) have found asymmetric pass-through related to the direction of exchange rate changes, while Ohno (1989) and Pollard and Coughlin (2004) have indicated the presence of asymmetry associated with the magnitude of exchange rate changes. The business cycle is also pointed out as an important source of nonlinearity for the pass-through. The transmission of exchange rate depreciations to domestic prices would be lower during an economic slowdown. Goldfajn and Werlang (2000), estimating a panel data model for 71 countries, have found that depreciations have a higher pass-through to prices when the economy is booming. In the case of Brazil, Carneiro, Monteiro and Wu 1 See, for instance, Chadha, Masson and Meredith (1992), Laxton, Meredith and Rose (1995), Dupasquier and Ricketts (1998), Nobay and Pell (2000), Aguiar and Martins (2002), Tambakis (1999), and Clements and Sensier (2003). 4 (2002) have found similar results estimating a backward-looking Phillips curve with the pass-through coefficient as a function of unemployment rate and real exchange rate level.3 In these papers, the magnitude of the pass-through coefficient is a function of some variables. This paper investigates the possibility of a nonlinear pass-through in Brazil using threshold models. These models are part of a class of models that consider different states of nature or regimes and allow different dynamic behavior for the variables, conditional on the regime prevailing in each moment (Franses and van Dijk, 2000). In the case of threshold models, the sample is divided into classes based on whether the value of an observed variable surpasses or not some threshold. This kind of model – Threshold Autoregressive (TAR) Model – was initially proposed by Tong (1978) and Tong and Lim (1980) and has spread in the recent applied economic literature. We focus on the pass-through because exchange rate movements have played a key role in the inflation dynamics in Brazil, especially in the early years of the inflation targeting regime with recurrent bouts of exchange rate depreciation in response to shocks, in the context of balance of payments vulnerabilities. We estimate three specifications for the Phillips curve, which differ basically by the variable used as the threshold for the passthrough: i) output gap; ii) nominal exchange rate change; and iii) exchange rate volatility. Thus, we can deal with different possible sources of nonlinearity. The first question is whether economic activity affects the magnitude of the pass-through. The second one is whether the pass-through is symmetric with respect to the direction of the exchange rate change – whether appreciations or depreciations have symmetric effects on prices – and to the magnitude of the exchange rate change. The estimations indicate that the short-run pass-through is higher when the economy is growing faster, when the exchange rate depreciates above a threshold value and when exchange rate volatility is lower. These results have implications for monetary policy and are possibly related to pricing-to-market behavior, costs of changing prices, and uncertainty regarding the degree of persistence of exchange rate changes. 2 Filardo (1998), in turn, considers that the Phillips curve is neither entirely convex nor concave, but a combination of both (a concave-convex curve). 3 Muinhos (2001) has found mixed results, and Bogdansky, Tombini and Werlang (2000) work with a model for Brazil with a nonlinear pass-through as well. 5 The article is organized as follows. Section 2 sets forth the methodology of threshold models with the presence of endogenous variables. Section 3 presents the specifications of the Phillips curve with threshold and the estimation results. The last section concludes the text. 2. Threshold models with endogenous variables In threshold models, the sample is divided into classes based on the value of an observed variable – whether it surpasses or not some threshold. As usual in practice, the threshold is not known and needs to be estimated. The simplest model is the SETAR (SelfExciting Threshold Autoregressive Model), where the threshold is given by a lagged term of the dependent variable – yt-d, where d>0. An AR(1) model of two regimes and d=1 can be written as: ⎧ φ01 + φ11 yt −1 + ε t if yt −1 〈 τ , yt = ⎨ 2 2 ⎩φ0 + φ1 yt −1 + ε t if yt −1 ≥ τ (1) where is the threshold value, φi j are the parameters i of the regime j, and ε t is an i.i.d. white noise sequence conditional on the history of the series, denoted by Ω t −1 = { yt −1 ,..., y t − p −1 , y t − p } , with zero mean and variance σ 2 . Alternatively, this model can be expressed as: yt = (φ 01 + φ11 yt −1 )[1 − I ( y t −1 〈 τ )] + (φ 02 + φ12 y t −1 ) I ( y t −1 ≥ τ ) + ε t , (2) where I(.) is an indicator function that takes a value equal to either one or zero, depending on the regime at time t. For these models with exogenous regressors, there is a well-developed theory of inference and estimation4. In the case of models with endogenous variables, in turn, the theory is still working in progress. Caner and Hansen (2004) develop an estimator and an 4 See, for example, Chan (1993), Hansen (1996, 1999, 2000) and Caner (2002). 6 inference theory for this kind of model, with the restriction that the threshold variable must be exogenous. A model with endogenous regressors can be described as follows. Let { yt , z t , xt }tn=1 be the information set, where yt is unidimensional, z t is an m-dimension vector (regressors), and xt is a k-dimension vector (instruments), with km. The threshold variable qt = q( xt ) can be an element or a function of the vector xt. In a general way, the structural equation can be written as: ⎧ yt = θ 1' zt + ζ t ⎨ ' ⎩ yt = θ 2 zt + ζ t qt 〈 τ , qt ≥ τ (3) or in a more compact way, yt = θ1' zt [1 − I (qt 〈 τ )] + θ 2' zt I (qt ≥ τ ) + ζ t , (4) where θ 'j are parameter vectors, τ ∈ Τ , and T is the set of the possible threshold values. Since the error term ζ t is correlated with z t – at least one variable in vector z t is endogenous – equation (4) cannot be estimated by ordinary least squares (OLS) because parameters would be biased and inconsistent. The method proposed by Caner and Hansen (2004) is based on the estimation of a reduced form equation for the endogenous variables as a function of instrumental variables, that is, a model with the conditional mean of the endogenous variables as a function of exogenous variables. The estimated values are plugged into structural equation (4) and the threshold value is estimated by minimizing the sum of the squared residuals. The parameters of the structural equation are estimated in a third step, when the sample is divided according to the estimated threshold. The estimation is conducted using the twostage least square method (2SLS) or the generalized method of moments (GMM). Therefore, the first stage (conditional expectations model of z t ) is given by: 7 z t = f ( xt , β ) + ut , (5) E (ut | xt ) = 0 , (6) where β is a vector with parameters, ut is the error term, and f (.,.) is a function. In particular, this function can also be conditioned on the threshold value (which can be equal or different from that in the structural equation):5 f ( xt , β ) = ( β 1' xt )[1 − I (qt 〈τ )] + ( β 2' xt )[ I (qt ≥τ )] . (7) The parameter vector β in equation (5) can be obtained by OLS, for each ∈ T, as: ⎞ ⎛ n βˆ1 (τ ) = ⎜⎜ ∑ xt xt' [ I (qt 〈τ )]⎟⎟ ⎠ ⎝ t =1 −1 n ⎛ n ⎞ βˆ 2 (τ ) = ⎜⎜ ∑ xt xt' [ I (qt ≥ τ )]⎟⎟ ⎝ t =1 ⎠ ∑ xt zt' [ I (qt 〈τ )] , (8) t =1 −1 n ∑ xt zt' [ I (qt ≥τ )] . (9) t =1 Using parameters β̂ , we can obtain the values ẑ t that will replace z t in the structural equation. Doing it recursively for every ∈ T, the threshold value in the structural equation can be chosen by the minimization of the sum of the squared residuals, using a grid search. For every , let Y, ZL and ZG denote the vector yt and the matrices z t [ I (qt 〈 τ )] e z t [ I (qt ≥τ )] , respectively. Thus, the threshold estimator is obtained from: τˆ = arg min S n (τ ) , (10) τ ∈T where S n (τ ) is the sum of the squared residuals in the regression of Y on Ẑ L and Ẑ G . The set of threshold values in (10) should be such that each regime has sufficient observations 5 In this paper, we do not condition on the threshold value in this first stage. 8 to generate reliable parameter estimation. According to Franses and van Dijk (1999), a safe choice is at least 15% of the sample. Given the estimated threshold value τˆ , the sample is divided into subsamples, and parameters of equation (10) can be estimated by 2SLS as: ( θˆ1 = ⎡ Zˆ L' Xˆ L Xˆ L' Xˆ L ⎢⎣ ( ) θˆ2 = ⎡ Zˆ G' Xˆ G Xˆ G' Xˆ G ⎢⎣ −1 ) ( −1 Xˆ L' Zˆ L ⎤ ⎡ Zˆ L' Xˆ L Xˆ L' Xˆ L ⎥⎦ ⎢⎣ −1 −1 ( ) Xˆ L' Y ⎤ , ⎥⎦ (11) ) (12) −1 Xˆ G' Zˆ G ⎤ ⎡ Zˆ G' Xˆ G Xˆ G' Xˆ G ⎥⎦ ⎢⎣ −1 Xˆ G' Y ⎤ , ⎥⎦ where Ẑ L , Ẑ G , X̂ L e X̂ G stand for the matrices with observations z t [ I (qt 〈τˆ)] , z t [ I (qt ≥τˆ)] , xt [ I (qt 〈 τˆ)] and xt [ I (qt ≥τˆ)] , respectively. Caner and Hansen (2004) show that those estimators are consistent, although not necessarily efficient. Their applicability is conditioned on the exogeneity of the threshold variable. 3. Phillips curve model for Brazil Aiming to test the possibility of the presence of a nonlinear pass-through from the exchange rate to inflation, we estimate some Phillips curve models for Brazil combined with the methodology of regime switching described in the previous section. The estimated Phillips curve relates inflation to a measure of real disequilibrium (output gap), inflation expectations, past inflation, exchange rate changes and external inflation, with a threshold variable: ⎧π tL = α11Etπ t +1 + (1 − α11 − α 21 )π t −1 + α 21 (Δet −1 + π t*−1 ) + α 41 yt −1 + ε t ⎨ L 2 2 2 2 * 2 ⎩ π t = α1 Etπ t +1 + (1 − α1 − α 2 )π t −1 + α 2 (Δet −1 + π t −1 ) + α 4 yt −1 + ε t if qt 〈 τ , if qt ≥τ (13) where α i j is the parameter of a specific regressor i when the economy is in regime j, π tL is free IPCA inflation (headline inflation measured by the Broad National Consumer Price 9 Index, but excluding administered prices), π t is headline IPCA inflation, π t* is a measure of external inflation (PPI in the U.S.), y t is output gap (actual minus potential output)6, et is the natural logarithm of the average nominal exchange rate (domestic currency units per dollar), Et(.) is the expectations operator conditional on the information available at t, Δ is the difference operator ( Δet −1 = et −1 − et − 2 ), ε t is a residual, qt is the threshold variable, and τ ∈T, where T is the set of possible values for qt . The dependent variable is the “free prices” component of headline inflation because administered prices have a different price dynamics, partially obeying contract rules. Note that the estimated pass-through refers to the transmission from exchange rate change in the previous quarter to the current inflation, that is, it captures only the short-run effect of exchange rate movements. To enable the joint estimation, the previous equations become: ( ) )(I [q ≥τ )+ ε π tL = α11Etπ t +1 + (1 − α11 − α 21 )π t −1 + α 21 (Δet −1 + π t*−1 ) + α 41 yt −1 (1 − I [qt 〈τ ) + (α 2 1 Etπ t +1 + (1 − α12 − α 22 )π t −1 + α 22 (Δet −1 + π t*−1 ) + α 42 yt −1 t . (14) t Based on theoretical indications for a nonlinear exchange rate pass-through, we evaluate three threshold variables: i) business cycle, measured by the output gap; ii) magnitude of nominal exchange rate changes; and iii) a measure of exchange rate volatility. We use quarterly data from 1995:1 through 2005:4 and estimate using 2SLS, with instrumental variables for the inflation expectations term. The first estimated specification has the output gap as the threshold variable. In this model, all parameters, except for that of the output gap, are subject to regime switching.7 The estimation results are the following (p-values in parentheses): 6 The output gap used in the estimation was generated using a production function model. See, for example, the box "Methodologies for estimating the potential output" in Banco Central do Brasil (2003) and Muinhos and Alves (2003) for a description of the methodology. 7 We do not allow the coefficient on output gap to change because we want to capture nonlinearities in the pass-through. 10 π tL = 0.75Et π t +1 + 0.25π t −1 + 0.00(Δet −1 + π*t −1 ) + 0.24 yt − 2 (0.00) (0.23) (0.78) ( 0.00) π tL = 0.58Et π t +1 + 0.33π t −1 + 0.09(Δet −1 + π*t −1 ) + 0.24 y t − 2 (0.02) (0.11) if yt −1 〈 − 1.89% (0.03) if y t −1 ≥ −1.89% ( 0.00) Sample period: 1995:1–2005:4 Standard errors estimated using Newey-West consistent estimators P-values in parentheses Impulse dummy variable for 1999:1: 0.02, p-value: 0.00 Instrumental variables: const., dummy variable, π t −1 , π t − 2 , Δet −1 , Δet − 2 , π t −1 , π t − 2 , y t − 2 R-squared: 0.50 Adjusted R-squared: 0.43 Breusch-Godfrey Serial Correlation LM test, p-values: 1 lag: 0.54, 4 lags: 0.33 White Heteroskedasticity Test, p-value: 0.27 Jarque-Bera Normality Test, p-value: 0.57 * * Wald test α 2 = α 2 , p-value: 0.04 1 2 According to the estimation results, there is a nonlinearity in the pass-through term related to the business cycle: the exchange rate pass-through is not statistically different from zero in the regime when the economy is below the threshold, whereas it is around 9% when economic activity is higher. According to the Wald test, we reject the null that the two pass-through coefficients are equal. The exchange rate pass-through is significantly greater when output is above some threshold8, estimated at 1.89% below the potential output. This means that, during an economic slowdown, an exchange rate variation will have a smaller impact on domestic prices. This is usually pointed as one of the factors that limited the pass-through in Brazil during the 1999 exchange rate crisis. One limitation of this result is its implication that exchange rate appreciations have a higher pass-through when the economy is booming than when the output gap is below the threshold. The other parameter estimates are in line with those found in the literature using models without a threshold variable. Except for the backward-looking term, all coefficients are statistically significant at 5%. In addition, the estimated value for the threshold splits the sample into two approximately equal parts (19 observations when y t −1 < −1.89 %, and 25 when y t −1 ≥ −1.89 %). This means that, although the sample size is not large, none of the 8 This result is in line with those in Goldfajn and Werlang (2000), and Carneiro, Monteiro and Wu (2002). 11 regimes was estimated with an extremely low number of observations.9 Actually, we have tried several specifications, using different instruments for the expectations term, and the results were robust. The second estimated model considers nominal exchange rate changes as the threshold variable. Similarly to the previous model, all parameters are allowed to vary with the regime change, except for the output gap parameter, kept constant in both regimes. The estimation results are the following10: π tL = 0.58Et π t +1 + 0.40π t −1 + 0.02(Δet −1 + π*t −1 ) + 0.27 yt −1 (0.00) (0.00) (0.31) if Δet −1 〈 2.10% ( 0.01) π tL = 0.44 Et π t +1 + 0.45π t −1 + 0.11(Δet −1 + π*t −1 ) + 0.27 y t −1 (0.10) (0.07) (0.03) if Δet −1 ≥ 2.10% ( 0.01) . Sample period: 1995:1–2005:4 Standard errors estimated using Newey-West consistent estimators P-values in parentheses Impulse dummy variable for 1999:1: 0.03, p-value: 0.08 Instrument variables: const., dummy var., π t −1 , π t − 2 , π t −3 , Δet −1 , Δet − 2 , π t −1 , π t − 2 , y t − 2 R-squared: 0.50 Adjusted R-squared: 0.43 Breusch-Godfrey Serial Correlation LM test, p-values: 1 lag: 1.00, 4 lags: 0.38 White Heteroskedasticity Test, p-value: 0.69 Jarque-Bera Normality Test, p-value: 0.31 * * Wald test α 2 = α 2 , p-value: 0.06 1 2 Those results indicate that the short-run effect of exchange rate changes on inflation is asymmetric. In the case of large exchange rate depreciations, the estimated pass-through for the following quarter is around 11%, whereas appreciations or small depreciations do not have a statistically significant effect. The Wald test rejects the null hypothesis that both coefficients are equal. Therefore, the pass-through is greater when quarter-on-quarter depreciations are equal to or larger than 2.1%. Although the results on the effect of an 9 Including the period previous to the launch of the Real Plan is not recommendable because the inflation dynamics in a high inflation regime is substantially different, distorting the estimation. 10 In that specification, we have used for the backward-looking inflation and output gap terms the average of ( ) ( ) their values at t-1 and t-2, that is, π t −1 = π A + π A / 2 and y t −1 = y A + y A / 2 , where the t −1 t−2 t −1 t−2 superscript A means actual values. That specification generates better fitting. 12 appreciation in the previous quarter on current inflation were not statistically significant, we should not infer that appreciations are not transmitted to prices. This transmission can take place with more lags than in the case of depreciation. As before, the estimated parameters are robust with respect to the instruments used and are statistically significant at 5% (except the coefficient on lagged inflation when Δet −1 ≥ 2.10% ). Moreover, the number of observations in each regime was reasonably balanced (15 observations in the large depreciation regime, and 29 in the other) and the estimated values for the coefficients are close to those reported in the literature. Note that in both estimations the forward-looking inflation coefficient is greater than the backwardlooking component. Since the estimated threshold is not zero, its slightly positive value (close to 2%) suggests the presence of menu costs or some adjustment costs of prices, where small exchange rate changes are not promptly transmitted to prices. If price changes are costly, a small change in the currency value can be accommodated within the markup margin. In this case, firms tend to postpone their decisions, adjusting their markup in the short-run. However, if exchange rate changes surpass some limit, even if the change is temporary, the costs of not adjusting prices are higher, leading firms to change prices more rapidly. Consequently, the presence of menu costs increases the possibility that firms will adjust price mainly if exchange rate changes surpass some threshold, resulting in an asymmetric pass-through related to small and large exchange rate changes. Furthermore, pricing-to-market theory delivers an explanation for a partial passthrough and for an asymmetry related to appreciations and depreciations in the exchange rate. Consider the domestic sector formed by subsidiaries of foreign firms that produce abroad and sell their products internally. In the case of an exchange rate depreciation, those firms have three options: i) to reduce their markup to keep stable the price in local currency (absence of pass-through); ii) to keep their markup, increasing the price charged in local currency to reflect completely the exchange rate change (complete pass-through), which may imply a market share reduction; or iii) a combination of the previous two possibilities (partial pass-through). When subsidiary firms are trying to build up or keep their market shares, a local currency depreciation results in a lower pass-through than that when there is an 13 appreciation. Nevertheless, if the depreciation of the domestic currency is high, there is less room for markup adjustments, and at least partially the depreciation is transmitted to domestic prices to avoid losses. In the case of appreciation, firms' profits increase if they keep constant domestic prices, which could result in a longer period to adjust prices downwards. The extension of these effects on the price level in the economy depends on the price-elasticity of demand for these firms’ goods and on the degree of openness of the economy. In addition, if the firms that produce abroad face a restriction on their production capacity, an exchange rate appreciation can result in a lower pass-through than in the case of a depreciation. The restriction capacity limits the fall in domestic price that the appreciation could generate. The previous estimated models do not make any distinction between the pre-1999 period, when the exchange rate was managed – following in practice a crawling peg system – and the following period of a floating rate. In fact, when we include a step dummy into the exchange rate term, the results deteriorate substantially in terms of signs and statistical significance of the parameters. This result may be related to the increase in the number of parameters to be estimated when we include a dummy variable, reducing the degree of freedom of the estimation. Because of those limitations, we have estimated a third model, using exchange rate volatility as the threshold variable. This estimation would tend to resolve, at least partially, the problem of the separation of the exchange rate regimes (before and after January 1999) because the threshold estimation tends to classify the observations of the managed system period into the low volatility regime. In principle, the low volatility estimated regime could also contain observations from when the exchange rate was relatively stable during the float period. In addition, that estimation aims to capture the inflationary effects in two different situations: i) when agents perceive exchange rate changes as transitory; and ii) when they perceive them as permanent. When agents consider exchange rate variations as more permanent, more promptly they will be transmitted to prices. Our assumption is that the probability that agents consider changes as permanent is higher in periods of low exchange 14 rate volatility and smaller in periods of greater volatility.11 Thus, we would expect a lower pass-through in periods of higher exchange rate instability. We have used the standard deviation of daily changes in the exchange rate within each quarter as the measure of volatility. The estimation results were the following12: π tL = 0.15 Etπ t +1 + 0.05π t −1 + 0.80(Δet −1 + π t*−1 ) + 0.31yt −1 (0.74) (0.83) (0.21) ( 0.00) π tL = 0.30 Etπ t +1 + 0.63π t −1 + 0.07(Δet −1 + π t*−1 ) + 0.31yt −1 (0.07) (0.00) if σ e,t −1 〈 0.07% (0.05) if σ e,t −1 ≥ 0.07% ( 0.00) . Sample period: 1995:1–2005:4 Standard errors estimated using Newey-West consistent estimators P-values in parentheses Impulse dummy variable for 1999:1: 0.03, p-value: 0.00 Instrumental variables: const., dummy variable, π t −1 , π t − 2 , Δet −1 , Δet − 2 , π t −1 , π t − 2 , yt −1 R-squared: 0.52 Adjusted R-squared: 0.45 Breusch-Godfrey Serial Correlation LM test, p-values: 1 lag: 0.69, 4 lags: 0.22 White Heteroskedasticity Test, p-value: 0.31 Jarque-Bera Normality Test, p-value: 0.21 * * Wald test α 2 = α 2 , p-value: 0.25 1 2 In terms of magnitude, the point estimates indicate a greater pass-through in low volatility periods than in high volatility moments (80% and 7%, respectively). However, the estimated pass-through is not statistically significant in the low volatility regime, although it is significant in the other regime and the parameter values are close to those reported in the literature for the periods of managed and floating exchange rates.13 The resulting sample division assigned most of the observations of the managed system to the 11 Albuquerque and Portugal (2006), for example, explore the relationship between exchange rate volatility and inflation in Brazil, using a bivariate GARCH model. 12 In that specification, we have used for the backward-looking inflation term the average of their values at t- ( ) 1, t-2 and t-3, that is, π t −1 = π A + π A + π A / 3 , and for the output gap term, the average at t-1 and tt −1 t−2 t −3 ( ) 2, that is, y t −1 = y A + y A / 2 , where the superscript A means actual values. That specification has t −1 t−2 generated better fitting. 15 low volatility regime. The observations corresponding to values below the threshold comprise the 1995:4–1998:2 period. Nevertheless, according to the Wald test, we cannot reject the null that both coefficients are equal, and the results of this Phillips curve specification are less robust than those of the two previous models. Therefore, these results should be considered with more caution. Figure 1 illustrates the results concerning the first model estimated. It presents the quarterly free price inflation, the exchange rate change (lagged one period), and a line that indicates the threshold value (-1.89%) of output gap. This line separates the periods when output gap is above and below the threshold. We point out some periods, described in Table 1, in which the estimated model can explain, at least partially, the relation between exchange rate changes and free price inflation. The table records the corresponding values, besides including headline inflation (measured by IPCA). Figure 1 – Free price inflation, exchange rate changes and the output gap 7 40 Free price inflation (%) 5 25 4 3 10 2 1 -5 0 – d+ d -1 d + d + a+ -20 Exchange rate change (%) 6 -2 -3 -35 I II III IV I 1998 II III IV I 1999 Free price inflation II III IV I II III IV I II III IV I 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Period output gap above the thr eshol d Period output gap bel ow the threshold II III IV I II III IV I II III Exc hange rate change (t-1) 13 Muinhos and Alves (2003), por instance, have found a coefficient reduction from 51% to 6% after the change in the exchange rate regime, and Albuquerque and Portugal (2005), using a Kalman filter model, have estimated parameters values around 42% and 4%, respectively. 16 Table 1 – Inflation and exchange rate changes in selected periods Period 1999: II 2000:III 2001:II 2001:III 2002:III 2002:IV 2004:IV 2005:I 2005:II Characteristic – d + d + d + d + d + d + a + a + a Headline inflation in t-1 2.88 0.66 1.42 1.52 1.44 2.58 1.94 2.00 1.79 Headline inflation in t 1.05 3.18 1.52 2.33 2.58 6.56 2.00 1.79 1.34 Free price inflation in t-1 2.59 0.71 1.42 1.40 0.62 2.56 1.35 1.31 1.72 Free price inflation in t 0.49 1.93 1.40 1.41 2.56 6.34 1.31 1.72 1.40 Exchange rate change in t-1 39.33 1.64 4.39 12.69 4.87 22.30 -2.30 -6.80 -4.42 + Note: d means depreciation with booming d– means depreciation with recession + a means appreciation with booming – a means appreciation with recession The exchange rate change is calculated based on the quarterly exchange rate average In the second quarter of 1999 (immediately after the float), for instance, in spite of the 39% exchange rate depreciation in the previous quarter, free price inflation was only 0.49% and the headline inflation stood at 1.05%, both below the previous quarter values. In that period, the output gap was below the estimated threshold (economic slowdown), which implies, according to the model, a low pass-through to inflation. The depreciations in the third quarter of 2000 and during 2001, in turn, were followed by higher increases in the inflation rate. In that period, the output gap was higher than the estimated threshold. In mid-2002, when the economy was growing faster, a strong depreciation was accompanied by a great inflation rise. In the last quarter, for instance, when the depreciation in the previous quarter reached 22%, free price inflation went from 2.56% to 6.34%, and headline inflation rose from 2.58% to 6.56%. On the other hand, although inflation fell along 2005, it did not follow so promptly the exchange rate appreciation started in the last quarter of 2004. One possible explanation lies on the asymmetry of the short-run pass-through with respect to appreciation and depreciation, put in evidence by the model with the threshold given by exchange rate changes. Furthermore, initial movements of appreciation were possibly not perceived immediately as having longer duration, postponing the effect on prices. In fact, the model estimates the short-run pass-through, that is, the effect on current inflation of the change in 17 the exchange rate in the previous quarter. The appreciation contributed for the reduction in inflation, but probably with lags greater than one quarter. 4. Conclusions This paper explores the possibility of the presence of a nonlinear pass-through from the exchange rate to inflation in Brazil. We have estimated models for the Phillips curve combined with the methodology of threshold models. In these models, the parameter values depend on which regime the economy is, which are determined endogenously by means of an observed variable. The choice of variables used was based on the possible sources of nonlinearity of the pass-through reported in the literature. In particular, we have examined three sources: i) business cycle; ii) exchange rate changes; and iii) exchange rate volatility. The estimations indicate the presence of nonlinear mechanisms in the short-run pass-through in Brazil. The short-run pass-through is higher when the economy is booming, when the exchange rate depreciates above some threshold, and when exchange rate volatility is lower. These results have important implications for monetary policy and are possibly related to a pricing-to-market behavior, menu costs to change prices, and uncertainty about the degree of persistence of exchange rate changes. 18 References Aguiar, A. and M. F. Martins (2002), “Trend, cycle and nonlinear trade-off in the Euro-area – 1970-2001", CEMPRE. Albuquerque, C. R. and M. S. Portugal (2005), “Pass-through from exchange rate to prices in Brazil: An analysis using time-varying parameters for the 1980-2002 period”, Revista de Economía, Montevideo, 12(1): 17-73. Albuquerque, C. R. and M. S. Portugal (2006), “Testing nonlinearities between Brazilian exchange rate and inflation volatilities”, Banco Central do Brasil Working Paper Series no. 106, May Banco Central do Brasil (2003), Inflation Report, p. 116-18, Dec. Bean, C. (2000), “The convex Phillips curve and macroeconomic policymaking under uncertainty”, mimeo, London School of Economics. Blonigen, B. A. and S. E. Hayes (2002), “Antidumping investigations and the pass-through of antidumping duties and exchange rates”, American Economic Review, 92(4): 104461, Sept. Bogdansky, J., A. Tombini, and S. Werlang (2000), “Implementing inflation targeting in Brazil”, Banco Central do Brasil Working Paper Series no. 1, July. Caner, M. (2002), “A note on least absolute deviation estimation of a threshold model”, Econometric Theory, 18(3): 800-14, June. Caner, M. and B. Hansen (2004), “Instrumental variable estimation of a threshold model”, Econometric Theory, 20(5): 813-43, Oct. Carneiro, D., A. M. Monteiro, and T. Wu (2002), “Mecanismos não-lineares de repasse cambial para o IPCA”, Departamento de Economia PUC-Rio, Texto para Discussão no. 462, Aug. Chadha, B., P. Masson, and G. Meredith (1992), “Models of inflation and the costs of disinflation”, IMF Staff Papers, 39(2): 395-431, June. Chan, K. S. (1993), “Consistency and limiting distribution of the least squares estimator of a threshold autoregressive model”, The Annals of Statistics, 21(1): 520-533, Mar. Clements, M., and M. Sensier (2003), “Asymmetric output gap effects in Phillips curve and murk-up pricing models: evidence for the U.S. and the U.K”, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 50(4): 359-74, Sept. 19 Dupasquier, C. and N. Ricketts (1998), “Nonlinearities in the output-inflation relationship: Some empirical results for Canada”, Bank of Canada Working Papers no. 98-14, Aug. Eisner, R. (1997), “New view of the NAIRU”, In: Paul Davidson and Jan Kregel (eds.), Improving the global economy: Keynesian and the growth in output and employment, Edward Elgar Publishing Cheltenham, UK, and Lyme, U.S. Filardo, A. J. (1998), “New evidence on the output cost of fighting inflation”, Economic Review, 83(3): 33-61, 3rd Quarter. Franses, P. H. and D. Van Dijk (2000), Nonlinear time series models in empirical finance, Cambridge University Press. Gil-Pareja, S. (2000), “Exchange rates and European countries’ export prices: An empirical test for asymmetries in pricing to market behavior”, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 136(1): 1-23. Gil-Pareja, S. (2003), “Pricing to market behavior in European car markets”, European Economic Review, 47(6): 945-62, Dec. Goldberg, P. K. (1995), “Product differentiation and oligopoly in international markets: The case of the U.S. automobile industry”, Econometrica, 63(4): 891-951, July. Goldfajn, I. and S. Werlang (2000), “The pass-through from depreciation to inflation: A panel study”, Banco Central do Brasil Working Paper Series no. 5, July. Hansen, B. E. (1996), “Inference when a nuisance parameter is not identified under the null hypothesis”, Econometrica, 64(2): 413-30, Mar. Hansen, B. E. (1999), “Threshold effects in non-dynamic panels: Estimation, testing and inference”, Journal of Econometrics, 93(2): 345-68, Dec. Hansen, B. E. (2000), “Sample splitting and threshold estimation”, Econometrica, 68(3): 575-603, May. Laxton, D., G. Meredith, and D. Rose (1995), “Asymmetric effects of economic activity on inflation: Evidence and policy implications”, IMF Staff Papers, 42(2):344 -74, June. Laxton, D., D. Rose, and D. Tambakis (1999), “The U.S. Phillips curve: The case for asymmetry”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 23(9-10): 1459-85, Sept. Mahdavi, S. (2002), “The response of the U.S. export prices to changes in the dollar’s effective exchange rate: Further evidence from industrial level data”, Applied Economics, 34(17): 2115-25, Nov. 20 Mann, C. L. (1986), “Prices, profit margins, and exchange rates”, Federal Reserve Bulletin, 72(6): 366-79. Muinhos, M. K. (2001), “Inflation targeting in an open financially integrated emerging economy: The case of Brazil”, Banco Central do Brasil Working Paper Series no. 26, Aug. Muinhos, M. K., and S. A. L. Alves (2003), “Medium-size macroeconomic model for the Brazilian economy”, Banco Central do Brasil Working Paper Series no. 64, Feb. Nobay, A. R., and D. A. Peel (2000), “Optimal monetary policy with a nonlinear Phillips curve”, Economic Letters, 67(2): 159-64, May. Ohno, K. (1989), “Export pricing behavior of manufacturing: A U.S.-Japan comparison”, IMF Staff Papers, 36(3), 550-79, Sept. Olivei, G. P. (2002), “Exchange rates and the prices of manufacturing products imported into the United States”, New England Economic Review, 1st Quarter, 3-18. Pollard. P. S., and C. C. Coughlin (2004), “Size matters: Asymmetric exchange rate passthrough at the industrial level”, University of Nottingham, Research Paper Series, no. 2004/13. Schaling, E. (2004), “The nonlinear Phillips curve and inflation forecast targeting: Symmetric versus asymmetric monetary policy rules”, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 36(3): 361-86, June Stiglitz, J. (1997), “Reflections on the natural rate hypothesis”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(1): 3-10, Winter. Tambakis, D. N. (1999), “Monetary policy with a nonlinear Phillips curve and asymmetric loss”, Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics, 3 (4): 223-37, Jan. Tong, H. (1978), “On a threshold model”, in C.H. Chen (ed.), Pattern recognition and signal processing, Amsterdam, Sijthoff & Noordgoff, 101-41. Tong, H., and K. S. Lim (1980), “Threshold autoregressions, limit cycles, and data”, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series B, 42(3): 245-92. 21 Banco Central do Brasil Trabalhos para Discussão Os Trabalhos para Discussão podem ser acessados na internet, no formato PDF, no endereço: http://www.bc.gov.br Working Paper Series Working Papers in PDF format can be downloaded from: http://www.bc.gov.br 1 Implementing Inflation Targeting in Brazil Joel Bogdanski, Alexandre Antonio Tombini and Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa Werlang Jul/2000 2 Política Monetária e Supervisão do Sistema Financeiro Nacional no Banco Central do Brasil Eduardo Lundberg Jul/2000 Monetary Policy and Banking Supervision Functions on the Central Bank Eduardo Lundberg Jul/2000 3 Private Sector Participation: a Theoretical Justification of the Brazilian Position Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa Werlang Jul/2000 4 An Information Theory Approach to the Aggregation of Log-Linear Models Pedro H. Albuquerque Jul/2000 5 The Pass-Through from Depreciation to Inflation: a Panel Study Ilan Goldfajn and Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa Werlang Jul/2000 6 Optimal Interest Rate Rules in Inflation Targeting Frameworks José Alvaro Rodrigues Neto, Fabio Araújo and Marta Baltar J. Moreira Jul/2000 7 Leading Indicators of Inflation for Brazil Marcelle Chauvet Sep/2000 8 The Correlation Matrix of the Brazilian Central Bank’s Standard Model for Interest Rate Market Risk José Alvaro Rodrigues Neto Sep/2000 9 Estimating Exchange Market Pressure and Intervention Activity Emanuel-Werner Kohlscheen Nov/2000 10 Análise do Financiamento Externo a uma Pequena Economia Aplicação da Teoria do Prêmio Monetário ao Caso Brasileiro: 1991–1998 Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo e Renato Galvão Flôres Júnior Mar/2001 11 A Note on the Efficient Estimation of Inflation in Brazil Michael F. Bryan and Stephen G. Cecchetti Mar/2001 12 A Test of Competition in Brazilian Banking Márcio I. Nakane Mar/2001 22 13 Modelos de Previsão de Insolvência Bancária no Brasil Marcio Magalhães Janot Mar/2001 14 Evaluating Core Inflation Measures for Brazil Francisco Marcos Rodrigues Figueiredo Mar/2001 15 Is It Worth Tracking Dollar/Real Implied Volatility? Sandro Canesso de Andrade and Benjamin Miranda Tabak Mar/2001 16 Avaliação das Projeções do Modelo Estrutural do Banco Central do Brasil para a Taxa de Variação do IPCA Sergio Afonso Lago Alves Mar/2001 Evaluation of the Central Bank of Brazil Structural Model’s Inflation Forecasts in an Inflation Targeting Framework Sergio Afonso Lago Alves Jul/2001 Estimando o Produto Potencial Brasileiro: uma Abordagem de Função de Produção Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho Abr/2001 Estimating Brazilian Potential Output: a Production Function Approach Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho Aug/2002 18 A Simple Model for Inflation Targeting in Brazil Paulo Springer de Freitas and Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos Apr/2001 19 Uncovered Interest Parity with Fundamentals: a Brazilian Exchange Rate Forecast Model Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos, Paulo Springer de Freitas and Fabio Araújo May/2001 20 Credit Channel without the LM Curve Victorio Y. T. Chu and Márcio I. Nakane May/2001 21 Os Impactos Econômicos da CPMF: Teoria e Evidência Pedro H. Albuquerque Jun/2001 22 Decentralized Portfolio Management Paulo Coutinho and Benjamin Miranda Tabak Jun/2001 23 Os Efeitos da CPMF sobre a Intermediação Financeira Sérgio Mikio Koyama e Márcio I. Nakane Jul/2001 24 Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Shocks, Backward-Looking Prices, and IMF Conditionality Joel Bogdanski, Paulo Springer de Freitas, Ilan Goldfajn and Alexandre Antonio Tombini Aug/2001 25 Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Reviewing Two Years of Monetary Policy 1999/00 Pedro Fachada Aug/2001 26 Inflation Targeting in an Open Financially Integrated Emerging Economy: the Case of Brazil Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos Aug/2001 27 Complementaridade e Fungibilidade dos Fluxos de Capitais Internacionais Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo e Renato Galvão Flôres Júnior Set/2001 17 23 28 Regras Monetárias e Dinâmica Macroeconômica no Brasil: uma Abordagem de Expectativas Racionais Marco Antonio Bonomo e Ricardo D. Brito Nov/2001 29 Using a Money Demand Model to Evaluate Monetary Policies in Brazil Pedro H. Albuquerque and Solange Gouvêa Nov/2001 30 Testing the Expectations Hypothesis in the Brazilian Term Structure of Interest Rates Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Sandro Canesso de Andrade Nov/2001 31 Algumas Considerações sobre a Sazonalidade no IPCA Francisco Marcos R. Figueiredo e Roberta Blass Staub Nov/2001 32 Crises Cambiais e Ataques Especulativos no Brasil Mauro Costa Miranda Nov/2001 33 Monetary Policy and Inflation in Brazil (1975-2000): a VAR Estimation André Minella Nov/2001 34 Constrained Discretion and Collective Action Problems: Reflections on the Resolution of International Financial Crises Arminio Fraga and Daniel Luiz Gleizer Nov/2001 35 Uma Definição Operacional de Estabilidade de Preços Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho Dez/2001 36 Can Emerging Markets Float? Should They Inflation Target? Barry Eichengreen Feb/2002 37 Monetary Policy in Brazil: Remarks on the Inflation Targeting Regime, Public Debt Management and Open Market Operations Luiz Fernando Figueiredo, Pedro Fachada and Sérgio Goldenstein Mar/2002 38 Volatilidade Implícita e Antecipação de Eventos de Stress: um Teste para o Mercado Brasileiro Frederico Pechir Gomes Mar/2002 39 Opções sobre Dólar Comercial e Expectativas a Respeito do Comportamento da Taxa de Câmbio Paulo Castor de Castro Mar/2002 40 Speculative Attacks on Debts, Dollarization and Optimum Currency Areas Aloisio Araujo and Márcia Leon Apr/2002 41 Mudanças de Regime no Câmbio Brasileiro Carlos Hamilton V. Araújo e Getúlio B. da Silveira Filho Jun/2002 42 Modelo Estrutural com Setor Externo: Endogenização do Prêmio de Risco e do Câmbio Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos, Sérgio Afonso Lago Alves e Gil Riella Jun/2002 43 The Effects of the Brazilian ADRs Program on Domestic Market Efficiency Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Eduardo José Araújo Lima Jun/2002 24 Jun/2002 44 Estrutura Competitiva, Produtividade Industrial e Liberação Comercial no Brasil Pedro Cavalcanti Ferreira e Osmani Teixeira de Carvalho Guillén 45 Optimal Monetary Policy, Gains from Commitment, and Inflation Persistence André Minella Aug/2002 46 The Determinants of Bank Interest Spread in Brazil Tarsila Segalla Afanasieff, Priscilla Maria Villa Lhacer and Márcio I. Nakane Aug/2002 47 Indicadores Derivados de Agregados Monetários Fernando de Aquino Fonseca Neto e José Albuquerque Júnior Set/2002 48 Should Government Smooth Exchange Rate Risk? Ilan Goldfajn and Marcos Antonio Silveira Sep/2002 49 Desenvolvimento do Sistema Financeiro e Crescimento Econômico no Brasil: Evidências de Causalidade Orlando Carneiro de Matos Set/2002 50 Macroeconomic Coordination and Inflation Targeting in a Two-Country Model Eui Jung Chang, Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos and Joanílio Rodolpho Teixeira Sep/2002 51 Credit Channel with Sovereign Credit Risk: an Empirical Test Victorio Yi Tson Chu Sep/2002 52 Generalized Hyperbolic Distributions and Brazilian Data José Fajardo and Aquiles Farias Sep/2002 53 Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Lessons and Challenges André Minella, Paulo Springer de Freitas, Ilan Goldfajn and Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos Nov/2002 54 Stock Returns and Volatility Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Solange Maria Guerra Nov/2002 55 Componentes de Curto e Longo Prazo das Taxas de Juros no Brasil Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo e Osmani Teixeira de Carvalho de Guillén Nov/2002 56 Causality and Cointegration in Stock Markets: the Case of Latin America Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Eduardo José Araújo Lima Dec/2002 57 As Leis de Falência: uma Abordagem Econômica Aloisio Araujo Dez/2002 58 The Random Walk Hypothesis and the Behavior of Foreign Capital Portfolio Flows: the Brazilian Stock Market Case Benjamin Miranda Tabak Dec/2002 59 Os Preços Administrados e a Inflação no Brasil Francisco Marcos R. Figueiredo e Thaís Porto Ferreira Dez/2002 60 Delegated Portfolio Management Paulo Coutinho and Benjamin Miranda Tabak Dec/2002 25 61 O Uso de Dados de Alta Freqüência na Estimação da Volatilidade e do Valor em Risco para o Ibovespa João Maurício de Souza Moreira e Eduardo Facó Lemgruber Dez/2002 62 Taxa de Juros e Concentração Bancária no Brasil Eduardo Kiyoshi Tonooka e Sérgio Mikio Koyama Fev/2003 63 Optimal Monetary Rules: the Case of Brazil Charles Lima de Almeida, Marco Aurélio Peres, Geraldo da Silva e Souza and Benjamin Miranda Tabak Feb/2003 64 Medium-Size Macroeconomic Model for the Brazilian Economy Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos and Sergio Afonso Lago Alves Feb/2003 65 On the Information Content of Oil Future Prices Benjamin Miranda Tabak Feb/2003 66 A Taxa de Juros de Equilíbrio: uma Abordagem Múltipla Pedro Calhman de Miranda e Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos Fev/2003 67 Avaliação de Métodos de Cálculo de Exigência de Capital para Risco de Mercado de Carteiras de Ações no Brasil Gustavo S. Araújo, João Maurício S. Moreira e Ricardo S. Maia Clemente Fev/2003 68 Real Balances in the Utility Function: Evidence for Brazil Leonardo Soriano de Alencar and Márcio I. Nakane Feb/2003 69 r-filters: a Hodrick-Prescott Filter Generalization Fabio Araújo, Marta Baltar Moreira Areosa and José Alvaro Rodrigues Neto Feb/2003 70 Monetary Policy Surprises and the Brazilian Term Structure of Interest Rates Benjamin Miranda Tabak Feb/2003 71 On Shadow-Prices of Banks in Real-Time Gross Settlement Systems Rodrigo Penaloza Apr/2003 72 O Prêmio pela Maturidade na Estrutura a Termo das Taxas de Juros Brasileiras Ricardo Dias de Oliveira Brito, Angelo J. Mont'Alverne Duarte e Osmani Teixeira de C. Guillen Maio/2003 73 Análise de Componentes Principais de Dados Funcionais – Uma Aplicação às Estruturas a Termo de Taxas de Juros Getúlio Borges da Silveira e Octavio Bessada Maio/2003 74 Aplicação do Modelo de Black, Derman & Toy à Precificação de Opções Sobre Títulos de Renda Fixa Octavio Manuel Bessada Lion, Carlos Alberto Nunes Cosenza e César das Neves Maio/2003 75 Brazil’s Financial System: Resilience to Shocks, no Currency Substitution, but Struggling to Promote Growth Ilan Goldfajn, Katherine Hennings and Helio Mori 26 Jun/2003 76 Inflation Targeting in Emerging Market Economies Arminio Fraga, Ilan Goldfajn and André Minella Jun/2003 77 Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Constructing Credibility under Exchange Rate Volatility André Minella, Paulo Springer de Freitas, Ilan Goldfajn and Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos Jul/2003 78 Contornando os Pressupostos de Black & Scholes: Aplicação do Modelo de Precificação de Opções de Duan no Mercado Brasileiro Gustavo Silva Araújo, Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo, Antonio Carlos Figueiredo, Eduardo Facó Lemgruber Out/2003 79 Inclusão do Decaimento Temporal na Metodologia Delta-Gama para o Cálculo do VaR de Carteiras Compradas em Opções no Brasil Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo, Gustavo Silva Araújo, Eduardo Facó Lemgruber Out/2003 80 Diferenças e Semelhanças entre Países da América Latina: uma Análise de Markov Switching para os Ciclos Econômicos de Brasil e Argentina Arnildo da Silva Correa Out/2003 81 Bank Competition, Agency Costs and the Performance of the Monetary Policy Leonardo Soriano de Alencar and Márcio I. Nakane Jan/2004 82 Carteiras de Opções: Avaliação de Metodologias de Exigência de Capital no Mercado Brasileiro Cláudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo e Gustavo Silva Araújo Mar/2004 83 Does Inflation Targeting Reduce Inflation? An Analysis for the OECD Industrial Countries Thomas Y. Wu May/2004 84 Speculative Attacks on Debts and Optimum Currency Area: a Welfare Analysis Aloisio Araujo and Marcia Leon May/2004 85 Risk Premia for Emerging Markets Bonds: Evidence from Brazilian Government Debt, 1996-2002 André Soares Loureiro and Fernando de Holanda Barbosa May/2004 86 Identificação do Fator Estocástico de Descontos e Algumas Implicações sobre Testes de Modelos de Consumo Fabio Araujo e João Victor Issler Maio/2004 87 Mercado de Crédito: uma Análise Econométrica dos Volumes de Crédito Total e Habitacional no Brasil Ana Carla Abrão Costa Dez/2004 88 Ciclos Internacionais de Negócios: uma Análise de Mudança de Regime Markoviano para Brasil, Argentina e Estados Unidos Arnildo da Silva Correa e Ronald Otto Hillbrecht Dez/2004 89 O Mercado de Hedge Cambial no Brasil: Reação das Instituições Financeiras a Intervenções do Banco Central Fernando N. de Oliveira Dez/2004 27 90 Bank Privatization and Productivity: Evidence for Brazil Márcio I. Nakane and Daniela B. Weintraub Dec/2004 91 Credit Risk Measurement and the Regulation of Bank Capital and Provision Requirements in Brazil – A Corporate Analysis Ricardo Schechtman, Valéria Salomão Garcia, Sergio Mikio Koyama and Guilherme Cronemberger Parente Dec/2004 92 Steady-State Analysis of an Open Economy General Equilibrium Model for Brazil Mirta Noemi Sataka Bugarin, Roberto de Goes Ellery Jr., Victor Gomes Silva, Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos Apr/2005 93 Avaliação de Modelos de Cálculo de Exigência de Capital para Risco Cambial Claudio H. da S. Barbedo, Gustavo S. Araújo, João Maurício S. Moreira e Ricardo S. Maia Clemente Abr/2005 94 Simulação Histórica Filtrada: Incorporação da Volatilidade ao Modelo Histórico de Cálculo de Risco para Ativos Não-Lineares Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo, Gustavo Silva Araújo e Eduardo Facó Lemgruber Abr/2005 95 Comment on Market Discipline and Monetary Policy by Carl Walsh Maurício S. Bugarin and Fábia A. de Carvalho Apr/2005 96 O que É Estratégia: uma Abordagem Multiparadigmática para a Disciplina Anthero de Moraes Meirelles Ago/2005 97 Finance and the Business Cycle: a Kalman Filter Approach with Markov Switching Ryan A. Compton and Jose Ricardo da Costa e Silva Aug/2005 98 Capital Flows Cycle: Stylized Facts and Empirical Evidences for Emerging Market Economies Helio Mori e Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos Aug/2005 99 Adequação das Medidas de Valor em Risco na Formulação da Exigência de Capital para Estratégias de Opções no Mercado Brasileiro Gustavo Silva Araújo, Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo,e Eduardo Facó Lemgruber Set/2005 100 Targets and Inflation Dynamics Sergio A. L. Alves and Waldyr D. Areosa Oct/2005 101 Comparing Equilibrium Real Interest Rates: Different Approaches to Measure Brazilian Rates Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos and Márcio I. Nakane Mar/2006 102 Judicial Risk and Credit Market Performance: Micro Evidence from Brazilian Payroll Loans Ana Carla A. Costa and João M. P. de Mello Apr/2006 103 The Effect of Adverse Supply Shocks on Monetary Policy and Output Maria da Glória D. S. Araújo, Mirta Bugarin, Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos and Jose Ricardo C. Silva Apr/2006 28 104 Extração de Informação de Opções Cambiais no Brasil Eui Jung Chang e Benjamin Miranda Tabak Abr/2006 105 Representing Roomate’s Preferences with Symmetric Utilities José Alvaro Rodrigues-Neto Apr/2006 106 Testing Nonlinearities Between Brazilian Exchange Rates and Inflation Volatilities Cristiane R. Albuquerque and Marcelo Portugal May/2006 107 Demand for Bank Services and Market Power in Brazilian Banking Márcio I. Nakane, Leonardo S. Alencar and Fabio Kanczuk Jun/2006 108 O Efeito da Consignação em Folha nas Taxas de Juros dos Empréstimos Pessoais Eduardo A. S. Rodrigues, Victorio Chu, Leonardo S. Alencar e Tony Takeda Jun/2006 109 The Recent Brazilian Disinflation Process and Costs Alexandre A. Tombini and Sergio A. Lago Alves Jun/2006 110 Fatores de Risco e o Spread Bancário no Brasil Fernando G. Bignotto e Eduardo Augusto de Souza Rodrigues Jul/2006 111 Avaliação de Modelos de Exigência de Capital para Risco de Mercado do Cupom Cambial Alan Cosme Rodrigues da Silva, João Maurício de Souza Moreira e Myrian Beatriz Eiras das Neves Jul/2006 112 Interdependence and Contagion: an Analysis of Information Transmission in Latin America's Stock Markets Angelo Marsiglia Fasolo Jul/2006 113 Investigação da Memória de Longo Prazo da Taxa de Câmbio no Brasil Sergio Rubens Stancato de Souza, Benjamin Miranda Tabak e Daniel O. Cajueiro Ago/2006 114 The Inequality Channel of Monetary Transmission Marta Areosa and Waldyr Areosa Aug/2006 115 Myopic Loss Aversion and House-Money Effect Overseas: an experimental approach José L. B. Fernandes, Juan Ignacio Peña and Benjamin M. Tabak Sep/2006 116 Out-Of-The-Money Monte Carlo Simulation Option Pricing: the join use of Importance Sampling and Descriptive Sampling Jaqueline Terra Moura Marins, Eduardo Saliby and Joséte Florencio do Santos Sep/2006 117 An Analysis of Off-Site Supervision of Banks’ Profitability, Risk and Capital Adequacy: a portfolio simulation approach applied to brazilian banks Theodore M. Barnhill, Marcos R. Souto and Benjamin M. Tabak Sep/2006 118 Contagion, Bankruptcy and Social Welfare Analysis in a Financial Economy with Risk Regulation Constraint Aloísio P. Araújo and José Valentim M. Vicente Oct/2006 29 119 A Central de Risco de Crédito no Brasil: uma análise de utilidade de informação Ricardo Schechtman Out/2006 120 Forecasting Interest Rates: an application for Brazil Eduardo J. A. Lima, Felipe Luduvice and Benjamin M. Tabak Oct/2006 121 The Role of Consumer’s Risk Aversion on Price Rigidity Sergio A. Lago Alves and Mirta N. S. Bugarin Nov/2006 30